I appreciate once again being
invited to participate in your annual convention. The convention
theme, "Creating Sustainable Competitive Advantage," is
well chosen for an industry that continues to be characterized by
dramatic change.
This morning I should like to
address one aspect of response to change--the evolution of bank
supervision.
As the theme of your convention
suggests, the economic landscape is continually evolving. To
remain competitive, individual banks must adapt, and they have. It
is no less natural to expect that supervisory policies and
practices also would evolve and adapt over time. Banking
supervision is responding, though admittedly not as rapidly
as the industry itself. This is not necessarily all bad. The
physician's admonition "First do no harm" is a desirable
starting point for bank supervisors as well.
Nevertheless, significant
changes are in the pipeline. Today I would like to sketch the
framework that is now being developed, growing out of work at the
Federal Reserve, at other U.S. banking agencies, and by our
colleagues abroad. The outline of this framework was presented in
a consultative document released by the Basel Supervisors
Committee in June. The details are preliminary, but the concepts
are beginning to congeal and deserve your close attention,
especially if you wish to influence the eventual outcome of the
deliberations.
The first concept I would
highlight is that the scope and complexity of prudential policies
should conform to the scope and complexity of the bank entities to
which they are applied. This means, in practice, that few changes
to the present system are necessary for the vast majority of banks
in the United States. More broadly, however, a one-size-fits-all
approach to regulation and supervision is inefficient and,
frankly, untenable in a world in which banks vary dramatically in
terms of size, business mix, and appetite for risk. Even among the
largest banks, no two institutions have exactly the same risk
profiles, risk controls, or organizational and management
structure. Accordingly, prudential policies need to be customized
for each institution: The more complex an institution's business
activities, the more sophisticated must be our approach to
prudential oversight.
The need for a multi-track
approach to prudential oversight is particularly evident as we
face the reality that the megabanks being formed by growth and
consolidation are increasingly complex entities that create the
potential for unusually large systemic risks in the national and
international economy should they fail. No central bank can
fulfill its ultimate responsibilities without endeavoring to
ensure that the oversight of such entities is consistent with
those potential risks. At the same time, policymakers must be
sensitive to the tradeoffs between more detailed supervision and
regulation, on the one hand, and moral hazard and the smothering
of innovation and competitive response, on the other. Heavier
supervision and regulation designed to reduce systemic risk would
likely lead to the virtual abdication of risk evaluation by
creditors of such entities, who could--in such an
environment--rely almost totally on the authorities to discipline
and protect the bank. The resultant reduction in market discipline
would, in turn, increase the risks in the banking system, quite
the opposite of what is intended. Such a heavier hand would also
blunt the ability of U.S. banks to respond to crisis events.
Increased government regulation is inconsistent with a banking
system that can respond to the kinds of changes that have
characterized recent years, changes that are expected to
accelerate in the years ahead.
The desirability of limiting
moral hazard, and of minimizing the risks of overly burdensome
supervision and regulation, has motivated those of us associated
with the Basel exercise to propose a three-pillared approach to
prudential oversight. This approach emphasizes, and seeks to
strengthen, market discipline, supervision, and minimum capital
regulation.
Market Discipline
In trying to balance the necessary tradeoffs, and in contemplating
the growing complexity of our largest banking organizations, it
seems to us that the supervisors have little choice but to try to
rely more--not less--on market discipline--augmented by more
effective public disclosures--to carry an increasing share of the
oversight load. This is, of course, only feasible for those,
primarily large, banking organizations that rely on uninsured
liabilities in a significant way. To be sure, these organizations
already disclose a considerable volume of information to market
participants, and, indeed, there is ample evidence that market
discipline now plays a role in banking behavior. Nonetheless, the
scale and clarity of disclosures is better at some institutions
than at others and, on average, could be considerably improved.
With more than a third of large-bank assets funded by noninsured
liabilities, the potential for oversight through market discipline
is significant, and success in this area may well reduce the need
to rely on more stringent governmental supervision and regulation.
The channels through which
market discipline works are, of course, changes in access to funds
and/or changes in risk premia as banks take on or shed risk or
engage in certain types of transactions. The changing cost and
availability of bank funding affect ex ante risk appetites
of bank management and serve as market signals of a bank's
condition to market participants and to examiners. But the
prerequisite to the enhancement of market discipline in
conjunction with supervision and regulation is improvement in the
amount and kind of public disclosure that uninsured claimants need
about bank activities and on- and off-balance-sheet assets in
order to make informed judgments and to act on those judgments.
Information on loans by risk category and information on residual
risk retained in securitization are examples. The best way to
encourage more disclosures is not yet clear. Our intent is to
consult with the industry regarding the establishment of new
disclosure standards and ways to evaluate their application.
Supervision
Improved public disclosure will, we believe, not only enhance
market discipline but also create further incentives for
improvements in banks' risk-management practices and technologies.
Such improvements will enhance the supervisory pillar of
prudential oversight. If supervisors are comfortable with a bank's
internal risk-management processes, the most cost-effective
approach to prudential oversight would have supervisors tap into
that bank's internal risk assessments and other management
information. To be sure, some "transaction testing" of
risk-management systems by supervisors will necessarily remain.
But as internal systems improve, the basic thrust of the
examination process should shift from largely duplicating many
activities already conducted within the bank to providing
constructive feedback that the bank can use to enhance further the
quality of its risk-management systems. It is these internal bank
systems--coupled with public disclosure--that provide the first
line of defense against undue risk-taking. Indeed, it should be
emphasized that the focus of supervision and
regulation--especially for the larger institutions--should be even
less on detail and more on the overall structure and operation of
risk-management systems. That is the most efficient way to address
our interest in both the safety and soundness of the banking
system and the overall stability of financial markets.
Relying more extensively on
banks' internal risk-management systems can also be used to
enhance prudential assessments of a bank's capital adequacy. As
the Basel consultative document suggests, over time our
examination process for assessing bank capital adequacy would try
to use the same techniques that banks are, and will be, using to
evaluate their risk positions and the capital needed to support
these risks. To spur this process in the United States, the
Federal Reserve in June issued new examination guidance
encouraging the largest and most complex banks to carry out
self-assessments of their capital adequacy in relation to
objective and quantifiable measures of risk. These
self-assessments will be evaluated during on-site examinations
and, eventually, are to be a factor in assigning supervisory
ratings.
A key component of these
self-assessments will be each bank's internal risk evaluations of
the credit quality of its customers and counterparties. Currently,
such internal risk ratings are beginning to be used by a small
number of banks in their risk-management, pricing, internal
economic capital allocation, and loan loss reserve determinations.
Some banks are further along in the process than others. Virtually
all large banks are moving in that direction. The bank regulators
already have begun incorporating reviews of these internal
risk-rating processes into their on-site examinations, and last
July the Federal Reserve issued examination guidance on this
subject, including a summary of emerging sound practices in this
area.
The supervisory policies and
procedures being contemplated will build on the increasingly
sophisticated management and control systems that are rapidly
becoming part of banks' best practice risk-management mechanisms.
They will, as well, require both good judgment and sophistication
on the part of bank examiners in order to avoid a cookie-cutter
application of policies and to develop skills at evaluation that
will match those available to the banks. For each of about thirty
large, complex banking organizations--in Washington parlance,
LCBOs--the Federal Reserve has already established dedicated teams
of examiners, supplemented by experts in areas ranging from
clearance and settlement to value-at-risk and credit-risk models.
Each LCBO team is directed by a senior Reserve Bank official. Both
that "central point of contact" and his or her
supervisory team will be charged with following one LCBO and
understanding its strategy, controls, and risk profile. Jointly,
these teams will represent the Federal Reserve supervisory pillar
as it applies to LCBOs.
Minimum Capital Regulation
In addition to emphasizing more effective market discipline and
making supervisory assessments of bank capital adequacy more
risk-focused, the June consultative paper highlights the need to
make regulatory capital requirements--the third pillar of
prudential oversight--more risk-focused as well. In recent years,
it has become clear that the largely arbitrary treatment of risks
within the current Basel Accord has distorted risk-management
practices and encouraged massive regulatory capital arbitrage.
That is, our rules have induced bank transactions that have the
effect of reducing regulatory capital requirements more than they
reduce a bank's risk position. Consequently, the fundamental
credibility of regulatory capital standards as a tool for
prudential oversight and prompt corrective action at the largest
banking organizations has been seriously undermined.
In reflection of the
considerable differences among banks that I mentioned earlier,
U.S. supervisors are developing proposals for a multi-track
approach to address modifications to the regulatory capital rules,
and this approach has been incorporated in the Basel consultative
document. Within the United States, consideration is being given
to a standardized capital treatment involving a quite simple
regulatory capital ratio that might become applicable to the vast
majority of institutions that are not internationally active. For
another group of banks, change might involve such modest
refinements to current capital requirements as closing certain
loopholes and basing some risk-weights on available external
credit ratings.
For those comparatively few
banking organizations whose scale, complexity, and diversity
warrant a more sophisticated approach to capital adequacy, the
Basel Committee has proposed another track that, at least
initially, would seek to link regulatory capital requirements to
the banks' internal risk ratings that I discussed earlier. Under
this approach, the risk-weight assigned to a particular credit
position would be based on the internal risk rating assigned by
the bank holding that instrument. Regulatory staffs in the United
States and other countries are currently attempting to work out
the basic architecture of such an approach. Critical issues
include how to validate banks' internal risk ratings and how to
link risk-weights to these internal ratings so as to ensure
economically meaningful and reasonably consistent capital
treatment of similar risks across banks. This is an extremely
difficult undertaking, and its success will require unprecedented
collaboration between--and among--supervisors and the banking
industry.
The Framework
It is, I believe, important to reiterate my earlier comment that
bank supervision and regulation--especially capital
regulation--are necessarily dynamic and evolutionary. We are
striving for a framework whose underlying goals and broad
strategies can remain relatively fixed, but within which changes
in application can be made as both bankers and supervisors learn
more, as banking practices change, and as individual banks grow
and change their operations and risk-control techniques.
Operationally, this means that we should not view innovations in
supervision and regulation as one-off events. Rather, the
underlying framework needs to be flexible and to embody a workable
process by which modest improvements in supervision and regulation
at the outset can be adjusted and further enhanced over time as
experience and operational feasibility dictate. In particular, we
should avoid mechanical or formulaic approaches that, whether
intentionally or not, effectively "lock" us into
particular technologies long after they become outmoded. We should
be planning for the long pull, not developing near-term quick
fixes. It is the framework that we must get right. The application
might initially be bare-boned but over time become more
sophisticated. For example, it could begin with a limited number
of risk "buckets" and, over time, be expanded to include
not only more risk categories, but also the use of an individual
bank's full credit-risk model--all within the same supervisory
framework and unique to each bank.
The design of the improved
oversight approach is a work in progress. We are endeavoring to
develop a program that is the least intrusive, most market based,
and most consistent with current and future sound risk-management
practices possible, given our responsibilities for financial
market stability.