This should be a time of great
satisfaction for the advocates of low-income and minority
borrowers. As a result of the good economy, various technological
changes, and innovative financial products, credit to low-income
and minority borrowers has exploded in recent years. Between 1993
and 1998, conventional home-purchase mortgage lending to
low-income borrowers increased nearly 75 percent, compared with a
52 percent rise for upper-income borrowers. Conventional mortgages
to African-Americans increased 95 percent over this period and to
Hispanics 78 percent, compared with a 40 percent increase in all
conventional mortgage borrowing. A significant portion of this
expansion of low-income lending appears to be in the so-called
subprime lending market. This market has expanded considerably,
permitting many low-income and minority borrowers to realize their
dream of owning a home and to have a chance for acquiring the
capital gains that have so increased the wealth of upper-income
households.
But with the good news there is
also bad news, or at least sobering news. Just as the expansion of
subprime lending has increased access to credit, the expansion of
its unfortunate counterpart, predatory lending, has made many
low-income borrowers worse off.
The distinction is important.
Subprime lending refers to lending to borrowers who do not qualify
for "prime" rates, those rates reserved for borrowers
with virtually blemish-free credit histories. Prime loans are
often described as "A" credits, and the mortgage
industry has adopted a grading scheme for subprime that extends
from A-minus through D. Premiums range from about 1 point over
prime for A-minus loans to about 6 points over prime for D loans.
These premiums have been questioned, and some have argued that
many low-income borrowers are still charged too much; but long-run
forces may eliminate inappropriate spreads. We would normally
expect that premiums in a market as competitive as mortgage
lending would at least move toward appropriate levels over time.
This optimistic story goes out
the window for what is known as predatory lending. Because the
practices are shady, information is incomplete and anecdotal. No
one knows how significant a problem, national or local, that
predatory lending really is. But we hear distressing reports of
abusive practices that include outright fraud, excessive fees and
interest rates, hidden costs, unnecessary insurance, and deceptive
uses of balloon payments. Self-explanatory labels from the
predatory markets are "loan flipping" and "equity
stripping." Horrifying anecdotes of predatory lending have
been standard fare for television expos�s and include a notable
congressional testimony of a witness with a bag over his head.
Recently a number of housing and banking agencies, including the
Federal Reserve, have announced their intention to study possible
restrictions on predatory lending. The Department of Housing and
Urban Development (HUD) has set up a national task force on the
topic. Members of Congress on both sides of the aisle have bills
that limit predatory practices.
The ultimate difference between
subprime and predatory lending comes back to the competitive
assumptions. If one is a market optimist and believes that both
lenders and borrowers are rational and well-informed, then
subprime credit markets with proper rate differentials will open
up. If one is a market pessimist and believes that borrowers are
not well-informed and may not be fully rational, then some lenders
will have opportunities to exploit these borrowers with predatory
practices. Distinguishing positive subprime lending from negative
predatory lending is obviously important, particularly for
regulators trying to encourage one type of lending and discourage
the other.
Who Does Subprime or
Predatory Lending?
Subprime lending tends to be done primarily by nondepository
institutions, either finance companies or mortgage companies that
are not subject to routine regulatory compliance audits and
connected with regulated financial institutions. These subprime
lenders generally raise money directly from bond or equity markets
and make subprime loans. In the mortgage market relatively few of
these loans are for first-time mortgages--mostly they are for
mortgage refinancings, second mortgages, or consolidating debt.
Often these loans are securitized and sold to investors such as
insurance companies and pension funds.
HUD compiles an annual list of
the subprime lenders that report data under the Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act (HMDA). For 1998, this list showed 239 subprime
lenders, of which 168 were regulated only by the Federal Trade
Commission (FTC). Thirty-six of these institutions were banks or
subsidiaries of banks and savings and loans that were regulated,
and the remaining thirty-five were banks or subsidiaries of bank
holding companies, where the holding company was regulated but the
subsidiary operated with some freedom from the holding company and
its regulator.
As mentioned earlier, one
distinguishes predatory lending from subprime lending by the
features of the loan and, importantly, by whether the borrower
understands the terms of the loan. Thus, there is no ready way to
distinguish predatory from subprime lending, to identify predatory
lenders, or to measure amounts. Yet most anecdotal reports or
legal cases against predatory lenders have involved subprime
lenders, and it is certainly logical to expect these practices to
flourish where the regulators are more remote. And the numbers
given above suggest that most subprime lenders are reasonably
sheltered from the normal bank regulatory apparatus.
What Do Predatory Lenders Do?
Predatory lending is made possible by inadequate information or,
in technical jargon, asymmetric information held by lenders and
borrowers. The fundamental weakness is the desire of low-income,
uneducated borrowers for cash up front. In part, this desire
reflects the ever-present needs of these low-income borrowers for
cash, often for badly needed home repairs. In part, it reflects
what might be called myopia, the illogical balancing of relatively
small up-front amounts compared with huge downstream borrowing
costs. In part, it reflects the lack of understanding of complex
credit terms or conditions in which insurance is and is not
needed. In part, it reflects bargaining imbalances where borrowers
are subjected to outright fraud, falsifications, and even forgery.
A significant component of
predatory lending involves outright fraud and deception, practices
that are clearly illegal. The policy response should simply be
better enforcement. But the harder analytical issue involves
abuses of practices that do improve credit market efficiency most
of the time. Mostly the freedom for loan rates to rise above
former usury law ceilings is desirable, in matching relatively
risky borrowers with appropriate lenders. But sometimes very high
interest rates can spell financial ruin for borrowers. Most of the
time, balloon payments make it possible for young homeowners to
buy their first house and match payments with their rising income
stream. But sometimes balloon payments can ruin borrowers who do
not have a rising income stream and are unduly influenced by the
up-front money. Most of the time the ability to refinance
mortgages permits borrowers to take advantage of lower mortgage
rates, but sometimes easy refinancing means high loan fees and
unnecessary credit costs. Often mortgage credit insurance is
desirable, but sometimes the insurance is unnecessary, and
sometimes borrowers pay premiums up front without the ability to
cancel the insurance and get a rebate when the mortgage is paid
off. Generally advertising enhances information, but sometimes it
is deceptive. Most of the time disclosure of mortgage terms is
desirable, but sometimes key points are hidden in the fine print.
Apart from outright fraud, these
are the fundamental characteristics of predatory lending. Mortgage
provisions that are generally desirable, but complicated, are
abused. For these generally desirable provisions to work properly,
both lenders and borrowers must fully understand them. Presumably
lenders do, but often borrowers do not. As a consequence,
provisions that work well most of the time end up being abused and
hurting vulnerable people enormously some of the time. Similarly,
lenders outside the bank regulatory system may help improve the
economic efficiency of low-income credit markets most of the time,
but act as unregulated rogue elephants some of the time.
Both factors make the regulatory
issues very difficult. Again, apart from outright fraud,
regulators and legislators feel understandably reluctant to outlaw
practices, if these practices are desirable most of the time.
Lenders can sometimes be brought into the bank regulatory system,
but others always could spring up outside this system. The FTC is
there to regulate trade practices in general, but that agency has
a huge job in policing all loan contracts.
What Can be Done?
In response to earlier reports of fraudulent lending, the Congress
in 1994 passed the Home Ownership Equity Protection Act (HOEPA).
HOEPA defined a class of "high cost" home purchase
loans, loans that charge closing fees of 8 points or more, or have
an annual percentage interest rate (APR) 10 percentage points
above prevailing Treasury rates for loans with comparable
maturities. For these HOEPA-protected loans there are thorough
disclosure requirements and prohibitions of many practices. There
can be no balloon payments in the first five years of a loan.
Certain prepayment penalties are prevented, as are negative
amortization loans and some advance payments. While most analysts
consider HOEPA to have been effective, we hear reports of lenders
skating just below the HOEPA requirements and still engaging in
egregious practices.
The logic of HOEPA is that in
this high-cost corner of the mortgage market, practices that are
generally allowable are not permitted, because the possibilities
of abuse are too high. Most present attempts to deal with
predatory lending try to broaden the HOEPA net, by lowering the
threshold cost levels and by preventing more practices. On the
Democratic side of the political aisle, Senator Sarbanes and
Representative LaFalce, from neighboring Buffalo, broaden the
HOEPA definition of high-cost loans to those with an APR 6 points
above Treasury rates for comparable maturities, and prevents life
insurance that is paid for with a single up-front premium. On the
Republican side, Representative Ney from Ohio broadens the HOEPA
definition to loans with an APR 8 or 9 points above Treasury
rates; and tightens the rules on prepayment penalties. There are
several other bills, generally taking similar approaches to the
problem.
Many states have also attempted
legislative remedies. Last July, North Carolina enacted amendments
to its usury laws that also broaden the HOEPA net. North
Carolina's law prohibits prepayment penalties, loan-flipping, and
single-premium credit life insurance on most home loans. For
high-cost loans, defined as loans with up-front fees greater than
5 percent of the loan or an APR of 10 percentage points above the
comparable Treasury rate, the law requires borrower counseling
before closing and prevents a number of practices: balloon
payments, negative amortization, lending without consideration of
the ability to pay, and financing of up-front fees or insurance
premiums.
Many other states are now using
this North Carolina legislation as a model for statutes of their
own. The list includes Illinois, Kansas, Maryland, Minnesota,
Missouri, South Carolina, Utah, and West Virginia. One such bill
has been introduced in New York State, but here the primary focus
has been regulatory. Last year the State Banking Board approved a
regulation patterned after HOEPA. It would apply to
home-improvement loans and have lower APR and point thresholds
than the federal statute has.
Other federal statutes address
predatory lending less directly. The Truth in Lending Act (TILA)
requires all creditors to calculate and disclose costs in a
uniform matter. Under this statute, lenders must disclose
information on payment schedules, prepayment penalties, and the
total cost of credit, expressed as a dollar amount and as an APR.
The Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act (RESPA) prohibits
lenders from paying fees to brokers that are not reasonably
related to the value of services performed by the broker. The
Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA) prohibits discrimination in
lending on the basis of a number of "prohibited basis
characteristics" such as age and race. The Federal Trade
Commission Act prohibits unfair and deceptive practices.
And yet, with all this
legislation, predatory lending seems to go on. Struck by these
potential weaknesses in the regulatory nets, the Federal Reserve
last fall convened an nine-agency working group to come up with
other approaches or common approaches. The relevant agencies are
the five that regulate depository institutions (the Federal
Reserve, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the Office of Thrift
Supervision, and the National Credit Union Administration), two
that regulate housing (HUD and the Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight) and two that regulate or prosecute deceptive
trade practices in general (the Department of Justice and the
FTC). The complete regulatory net of these agencies would cover
all predatory lending, though the FTC, for example, might be hard
pressed to go after all lending operations outside the primary
depository institution net. The aims of the group are to tighten
enforcement of existing statutes, to identify those predatory
practices that might be limited by tightened regulations or
legislative changes, and in general to establish a coordinated
attack on predatory practices.
HUD has also recently announced
a task force to combat predatory lending. HUD administers RESPA
and may be envisioning tightening its procedures. HUD's Federal
Housing Administration (FHA) has also recently started requiring
mandatory testing of real estate appraisers and an assessment of
the physical condition of properties in its own lending programs.
Secondary mortgage institutions
such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac also plan to enter the subprime
business. If Fannie and Freddie were merely to buy subprime loans
without added inspection, these secondary market institutions
could actually subsidize predatory lending. But if Fannie and
Freddie were to inspect the practices of subprime lenders from
whom they purchase loans, or to limit purchases of certain types
of loans, they might effectively extend the domain of subprime
regulations.
A final factor is consumer
education. Predatory lending would not exist, or would be
relatively rare, if prospective borrowers understood the true
nature of their loan contracts. The Neighborhood Reinvestment
Corporation (NRC) has an active borrower education program to
promote just that type of understanding, and many other public and
quasi-public agencies are thinking of following suit. To this
point, efforts to extend consumer financial education into high
schools have proven very disappointing, but there have been some
successes with stock market simulation exercises. Perhaps some of
these efforts could be extended to predatory lending issues.
Conclusion
Predatory lending is a difficult issue. It causes obvious
difficulties for borrowers, it is difficult for enforcers to track
down, and it is difficult to regulate. So far as we can tell,
predatory lenders generally operate outside the main financial
regulation network. These lenders are sometimes fraudulent, but
probably more often they take advantage of loan terms that are
useful for many borrowers but can become destructive if
misunderstood by some borrowers. They also take advantage of
low-income and less-educated borrowers who need cash up front and
are unlikely to understand the provisions. When and if borrowers
default, they can either lose their house or be induced to sign up
for still more exploitative terms.
Because predatory lenders are
less regulated and predatory loans are often difficult to identify
and define legally, it becomes both a regulatory and an
enforcement challenge to stop predatory practices. Currently, nine
agencies are meeting to design a coordinated attack on the
problem, and a number of legislative options are under
consideration in both the federal and state legislatures. The goal
is to eliminate or limit some sorry practices that are the
unfortunate byproduct of recent efforts to democratize credit
markets.