I am pleased to participate in
today's conference and to join others in the justly deserved
tributes to Anna Schwartz. She has been most interested, among a
wide variety of other subjects, in the connections that economic
and financial policies have to financial crises. As a consequence,
I have decided to speak about technology and financial services,
and particularly about risk management, issues that I have spent a
good deal of time addressing in recent years. As a related matter,
I will comment on supervision and regulation as we move into the
twenty-first century, and of course, I shall find a way to touch
on the role of central banks.
Without doubt, the acceleration
in technology that has produced such an extraordinary effect upon
our economy in general has had a particularly profound impact in
expanding the scope and utility of financial products over the
last fifteen years. Information technology has made possible the
creation, valuation, and exchange of complex financial products on
a global basis heretofore envisioned only in our textbooks, and
even that just in recent years. Derivatives are obviously the most
evident of the many products that technology has inspired. But the
substantial increase in our calculation capabilities has permitted
the putting into place of a variety of other products and, most
beneficially, new ways to unbundle risk. What is really quite
extraordinary is that there is no sign that this process of
acceleration in financial technology is approaching an end. We are
moving at an exceptionally rapid pace, fueled not only by the
enhanced mathematical applications produced by our ever-rising
computing capabilities but also by our expanding
telecommunications capabilities and the associated substantial
broadening of our markets.
All the new financial products
that have been created in recent years contribute economic value
by unbundling risks and reallocating them in a highly calibrated
manner. The rising share of finance in the business output of the
United States and other countries is a measure of the economic
value added by the ability of these new instruments and techniques
to enhance the process of wealth creation. The reason, of course,
is that information is critical to the evaluation of risk. The
less that is known about the current state of a market or a
venture, the less the ability to project future outcomes and,
hence, the more those potential outcomes will be discounted.
Financial intermediation,
although it cannot alter the underlying risk in holding direct
claims on real assets, can redistribute risks in a manner that
alters behavior. This redistribution of risk induces more
investment in real assets, presumably engendering a higher
standard of living. This occurs because financial intermediation
facilitates diversification of risk and its redistribution among
people with different attitudes toward risk. Any mechanism that
shifts risk from those who choose to withdraw from it to those
more willing to take it on increases investment without
significantly raising the perceived degree of discomfort from risk
borne by the public.
By itself, more abundant
real-time information should both reduce the uncertainties and
lower the variances employed to guide portfolio decisions. At
least part of the observed fall in equity premiums in our economy
and others over the past five years may have resulted from a
permanent technology-driven increase in information availability,
which by definition reduces uncertainty and therefore risk
premiums. And because knowledge once gained is irreversible, so
too are the lowered risk premiums.
But while financial
intermediation, through its impetus to diversification, can lower
the risks of holding claims on real assets, it cannot alter the
more deep-seated uncertainties inherent in the human evaluation
process. There is little in our historical annals that suggests
that human nature has changed much over the generations. But, as I
have noted previously, while time preference may appear to be
relatively stable over history, perceptions of risk and
uncertainty, which couple with time preference to create discount
factors, obviously vary widely, as does liquidity preference,
itself a function of uncertainty. These uncertainties are an
underlying source of risk that are too often regarded as
background noise and are generally not captured in our risk
models.
I have previously called
attention to changing risk perceptions as a risk-management
challenge in a different context when discussing the roots of the
recent international financial crises. My focus has been on the
perils of risk management when periodic crises--characterized by
sharply rising risk premiums--undermine risk-management structures
that fail to address them.
During a financial crisis, risk
aversion rises dramatically, and deliberate trading strategies are
replaced by rising fear-induced disengagement from market
activity. It is the general human experience that when confronted
with uncertainty, whether in financial markets or in any other
aspect of life, disengagement is the normal protective reaction.
In markets that are net long, the most general case, disengagement
brings falling prices. In the more extreme manifestation, the
inability or unwillingness to differentiate among degrees of risk
drives trading strategies to seek ever-more-liquid instruments
that presumably would permit investors immediately to reverse
decisions at minimum cost should that be required. As a
consequence, even among riskless assets, such as U.S.
Treasury securities, liquidity premiums rise sharply as investors
seek the heavily traded "on-the-run" issues--a behavior
that was so evident in the fall of 1998.
While we can readily describe
the process of sharp reversals in confidence, to date economists
have been unable to anticipate it. Nevertheless, if episodic
recurrences of ruptured confidence are integral to the way our
economy and our financial markets work now and in the future, the
implications for risk measurement and risk management are
significant.
Probability distributions
estimated largely, or exclusively, over cycles that do not include
periods of panic will underestimate the likelihood of extreme
price movements because they fail to capture a secondary peak
associated with extreme negative outcomes. Furthermore, joint
distributions estimated over periods that do not include
panics will underestimate correlations between asset returns during
panics. Under these circumstances, fear and hence disengagement on
the part of investors holding net long positions often lead to
simultaneous declines in the values of private obligations, as
investors no longer materially differentiate among degrees of risk
and liquidity, and to increases in the values of riskless
government securities. Consequently, the benefits of portfolio
diversification will tend to be overestimated when the rare panic
periods are not taken into account.
The uncertainties inherent in
valuations of assets and the potential for abrupt changes in
perceptions of those uncertainties clearly must be adjudged by
risk managers at banks and other financial intermediaries. At a
minimum, risk managers need to stress test the assumptions
underlying their models and consider portfolio dynamics under a
variety of alternative scenarios. The outcome of this process may
well be the recommendation to set aside somewhat higher
contingency resources--reserves or capital--to cover the losses
that will inevitably emerge from time to time when investors
suffer a loss of confidence. These reserves will appear almost all
the time to be a suboptimal use of capital, but so do fire
insurance premiums--until there is a fire.
More important, boards of
directors, senior managers, and supervisory authorities of
financial institutions need to balance emphasis on risk models
that essentially have only dimly perceived sampling
characteristics with emphasis on the skills, experience, and
judgment of the people who have to apply those models. Being able
to judge which structural model best describes the forces driving
asset pricing in any particular period is itself priceless. To
paraphrase my former colleague, Jerry Corrigan, the advent of
sophisticated risk models has not made people with gray hair, or
none, wholly obsolete.
More fundamentally, technology
may be affecting the underlying economics of financial
intermediation. One of the profound effects of technology on
financial services is that the increasing availability of accurate
and relevant real-time information, by reducing uncertainty,
reduces the cost of capital. That is to say, the cost of capital
is lower for both lenders and borrowers and for banks in their
role as both. It is important to a bank as a borrower because
funding costs are critically tied to the perceived level of
uncertainty surrounding the institution's condition. It is
important in the role of lender because a decline in uncertainty
resulting from a substantial increase in real-time information
implies a reduction in what might be called "knowledge
float"--the ability to maintain proprietary information and
earn a rate of return from that information with no cost. As you
know, financial intermediaries historically have been successful
not only because they diversified to manage risk but also because
they possessed information that others did not have. This
asymmetry of information was capitalized at a fairly significant
rate. But that advantage now is rapidly dissipating. We are going
to real-time systems, not only with transactions but with
knowledge as well.
Financial institutions can
respond to this disappearing advantage by endeavoring to preserve
the old way of doing business--by keeping information, especially
adverse information, away from the funders of their liabilities.
But that, I submit, is a foolish policy that buys a dubious
short-term gain with a substantial long-term cost. Moreover,
inevitably and increasingly it will become more difficult to do.
Whenever it becomes clear that the information coming out of an
institution is somehow questionable, that institution will pay an
uncertainty premium. Conversely, when companies write off errors,
their stock prices almost invariably rise. The reason is the
removal of uncertainty and the elimination of a shadow on the
company's credibility.
What does all this mean for
financial supervision and regulation? If the supervisory system is
to remain effective in fostering the safety and soundness of the
country's financial system, it must adjust to the changing
structure of that system. When wearing our supervisory hat at the
Federal Reserve, we and our sister agencies are always working to
move in a manner that facilitates and fosters innovation. We are
in a dynamic system that requires not just us but our colleagues
around the world to adjust as well.
Today's financial products and
rapidly changing structures of finance mean the old-fashioned,
nineteenth- and twentieth-century presumption that a month-old
balance sheet is telling us all we need to know about an
institution's current condition is long since gone. Inevitably,
therefore, we as supervisors are recognizing this reality and have
been placing greater emphasis on how well internal risk models are
functioning and whether the risk thus measured is being
appropriately managed and offset with reasonable hedges. We are
also scrutinizing how well an institution is able to tie its risk
exposures to internal capital needs. We have a long way to go, but
this is where competitive pressures and the underlying economic
forces are pushing both financial intermediaries and the
supervisory system.
There is a broader and more
difficult problem of risk management that central bankers confront
every day, whether we explicitly acknowledge it or not: How much
of the underlying risk in a financial system should be shouldered
by banks and other financial institutions. Clearly, were we to
require that bank risk-management systems, for example, provide
capital to address all conceivable risks that could bring
failure, the rates of return on capital would fall, and the degree
of financial intermediation and leverage, as a consequence, would
inevitably decline.
The degree of leverage in
financial systems is obviously tied to the degree of risk at the
margin of lending. Before the creation of the Federal Reserve and,
later, deposit insurance, banks were forced by the marketplace to
hold 20 percent and more of their assets as capital if they wanted
to sell their liabilities at minimum interest costs.
By its actions in the
marketplace and its chosen governmental structure, society reveals
its preference for trading off leverage with its underlying risks
and economic growth. Few, I presume, would argue that zero
leverage is optimum. Fewer would argue that zero leverage is
consistent with maximum growth. Yet the dangers of too much
leverage are all too evident. In this context, how do we central
bankers and other supervisors read our very amorphous directive to
maintain financial stability and economic growth?
We have all chosen implicitly,
if not in a more overt fashion, to set our capital and other
reserve standards for banks to guard against outcomes that exclude
those once or twice in a century crises that threaten the
stability of our domestic and international financial systems.
I do not believe any central
bank explicitly makes this calculation. But we have chosen capital
standards that by any stretch of the imagination cannot protect
against all potential adverse loss outcomes. There is implicit in
this exercise the admission that, in certain episodes, problems at
commercial banks and other financial institutions, when their
risk-management systems prove inadequate, will be handled by
central banks. At the same time, society on the whole should
require that we set this bar very high. Hundred-year floods come
only once every hundred years. Financial institutions should
expect to look to the central bank only in extremely rare
situations.
I am obviously referring to far
more adverse outcomes than I was alluding to in my earlier remarks
on the need for private risk-management systems to adjust for
crises in their estimates of risk distributions. However, where
that dividing line rests is an issue that has not yet been
addressed by the international banking community. Clearly, to
choose the distribution of risk-bearing between private finance
and government is to choose the degree of moral hazard. I believe
we recognize and accept it. Indeed, making that choice may be the
essence of central banking.
In summary, then, although
information technology by its very nature has lowered risk, it has
also engendered a far more complex international financial system
that will doubtless bedevil central bankers and other financial
regulators for decades to come. I am sure that nostalgia for the
relative automaticity of the gold standard will rise among those
of us engaged to replace it.