I am very happy to return to Ann
Arbor to give the Winkelman Lecture. The lecture series was
established for the discussion of social and biological issues in
the field of gerontology. It takes a bit of a stretch to ask an
economist to comment on any issues in the field of gerontology,
and I am deeply honored to be invited. My topic today will be
social security, the federal government's largest and most popular
social program and the one with the clearest impact on the
financial well-being of older Americans.
Going beyond their mutual
contact with gerontology, there is a connection between the
Winkelman family and social security that I think most people
don't know about. Stanley Winkelman, one of the founders and
benefactors of this series and also a long-time and esteemed
philanthropist in this area, died last August. He was distantly
related to Wilbur Cohen, who was on the faculty of the School of
Social Work but, more relevantly, was also one of the drafters of
the original Social Security Act. It then seems very fitting to
give this first Winkelman Lecture after Stanley's death on social
security, a topic that he would have cared deeply about and a
program that his relative helped to create.
In fiscal year 1999, social
security paid $387 billion in benefits to 45 million people. These
benefits make up roughly 40 percent of the income received by aged
families and more than 80 percent of the income received by the
poorest aged families. Social security has not eliminated aged
poverty, but it has been largely responsible for a reduction in
the aged poverty rate from 35 percent back in 1959 to 11 percent
today. Because of its support to aged people of all incomes, poll
after poll has indicated social security's unique political
popularity. Politicians treat social security as the "third
rail" of American politics: "Touch it and you die."
The original Social Security Act
was passed back in 1935, the most significant and lasting domestic
policy achievement of Franklin Roosevelt's New Deal. The program's
history in the twentieth century was one of steady growth. The
combined employer-employee payroll tax to finance the program
started at 2 percent in 1937 and rose gradually through the years
to 12.4 percent by the close of the century. This tax was assessed
on the first $3,000 of wages in 1937 and is assessed on the first
$76,200 today. Coverage was sporadic at first, but the program now
covers more than 96 percent of the workforce. Normal program
benefits have also risen through time for covered workers. A
disability insurance program was added to the normal retirement
benefits in 1954, and benefits were automatically indexed for
inflation beginning in 1975.
But although growth was the
watchword in the twentieth century, many commentators now predict
a slowdown in program growth. The program is now mature, in the
sense that coverage is nearly universal and benefits automatically
rise at roughly the same rate as overall wages and salaries. But
unlike the situation for most of the twentieth century, as we move
to the twenty-first century the United States is looking at a
massive aging of its population. Whereas 16 workers paid taxes to
finance benefits back in 1950, the number has dropped to 3.4 now
and is slated to drop to 2 in another three decades. The
consequence is that it will take an immediate payroll tax
increase, now estimated at 2.6 percent (bringing the total to 15
percent), just to pay for the present benefit system over the
standard seventy-five year forecasting period, and a greater tax
increase if this period is extended even a few years. Yet unlike
in the twentieth century, when such a payroll tax increase would
have been the normal response to impending financial problems,
almost all politicians of either party now oppose further payroll
tax increases, and some advocate reductions. What worked
politically in the twentieth century may not work in the
twenty-first century.
In this talk I will try to
assess the economic and political outlook for social security, the
signature social program of the twentieth century, in the
twenty-first century. I will review the objectives that I believe
America should keep front and center in dealing with social
security, and some of the problems now facing the system. I will
comment on the experience of other countries: Many adopted their
own social security programs about the time that the United States
did, and many face similar problems with their own systems. Then I
will promote my own magic bullet of social security
reform--whatever else they do, reforms should try to raise
national saving, in effect prefunding future benefit payments.
Objectives and Problems
Social Protections
The fundamental objective in dealing with social security should
be to preserve its massive system of social protections. The
program contains some internal redistribution, in the sense that
returns on contributed payroll taxes are higher for low-wage
workers than for high-wage workers. These higher returns,
reflected in relatively higher benefit payments for lower-wage
retirees, largely explain why the program has been responsible for
so much reduction of poverty among the aged and partly explain why
social security accounts for such a high share of the retirement
income received by lower income retirees. In addition, the
disability program gives workers and their families protection
against the financial consequences of workplace disabilities.
Family members of workers who die prematurely receive early
survivor's insurance. Social security benefits are also real
annuities, which means that payments go on as long as retirees
live, with added protection for surviving spouses. Not only that,
but these benefits are automatically protected from inflation.
Social security is one of the few pension programs in America that
has this feature. All of these social protections have existed for
some time now, so long that they may be taken for granted.
Preserving them should be the first order of business.
Although preserving the main
social protections is fundamental, benefits could be improved or
modified. One obvious change is in coverage. Program coverage is
now nearly universal, except for a share of state and local
workers and some other workers in sectors that will eventually be
fully covered. A standard suggestion for program reform is to move
toward complete coverage, eliminating some minor inequities in the
process. A second suggestion involves poverty reduction. Because
of the way benefits for surviving spouses are computed, America
still has high poverty rates among aged widows, rates that are
much higher than those in other developed countries. There are
relatively simple and cheap ways to change the computation of
survivor benefits to cut into this high rate of aged widow
poverty.
Two other problems with the
benefit system receive most of the discussion. One involves the
so-called normal retirement age for the computation of benefits.
The social security system computes benefits through a formula
based on the payroll tax contributions that workers have paid into
the trust fund. This computation leads to a standard benefit
received at age sixty-five, the normal retirement age now, as
indeed it was back in 1935 when the program was established. But,
of course, workers live much longer now than they did then, and
the gradual lengthening of retirees' life spans is the major cause
of the financial problems now facing the system.
Workers can retire and collect
benefits as early as age sixty-two, taking an actuarial reduction
in benefits if they do so. They can also gain more benefits from
the delayed retirement credit if they work past age sixty-five.
Retirees who work are also subject to social security's earnings
test, a measure that has never made much sense in the logic of the
social security program, and that may not be with us much longer.
Previous legislation has the normal retirement age rising in steps
to age sixty-seven over the next two decades. Many have proposed
going beyond this legislation and tying the normal retirement age
to life expectancy, computing benefit payments on the assumption
that different cohorts of workers could be spending a constant
share of their expected lifetimes in working and retirement years.
Proposals to raise the normal
retirement age are hugely controversial, perhaps because they are
generally misunderstood. What is misunderstood is the fact that,
if workers are still permitted to retire and collect benefits at
age sixty-two, the rising normal retirement age really means only
a slight cut in benefits for workers retiring at any fixed age. It
does not mean that these workers would have to work until these
older ages. This slight cut in benefits may or may not be a good
idea--there are powerful arguments for making some cuts in
benefits, and no cut would be loved by everybody. At the same
time, it is legitimate to ask whether benefits should be cut in
this way or dispropor- tionately for higher income individuals who
may not have worked in physically arduous careers.
The second issue that commonly
arises on the benefit side reflects the fact that social security
is largely a social protection program, not a full program for
retirement benefits. Social security today provides most
retirement income for low-wage retirees but a lesser share as we
move up the income scale. The idea is that higher-wage retirees
should, if they wish to continue their pre-retirement living
standards, supplement social security with private pensions and
their own saving. Unfortunately, many do not. Roughly 40 percent
of households in the $25,000 to $50,000 income class do not have
pensions, and roughly 30 percent of households with incomes above
$50,000 do not have pensions. These workers at least ought to be
thoroughly warned about the impending decline in their standard of
living, perhaps induced to save more by tax incentives, and
perhaps even required to save more. I'll return to this saving
issue below.
Actuarial Balance
From its inception, social security has been set up in a very
responsible way financially. Employer and employee taxes, along
with a small amount of revenue from the income taxation of
benefits, go into a trust fund that is used to pay social security
benefits. For the first forty years of its history this trust fund
ran on a pay-as-you-go basis. Current payroll tax revenues were
used to pay benefits, with little system for accumulating assets.
Program changes made in the 1980s moved slightly toward the
prefunding of benefits. The coming demographic shift was
well-recognized in the 1980s, and changes made then raised payroll
taxes ahead of benefit payments, with the consequence that the
social security trust fund is now running a cash surplus of about
$150 billion per year, rising by about $15 billion a year for the
next few years. This surplus is invested in government securities,
with social security credited for all interest on these
securities. Political talk about stealing social security benefits
to finance the rest of government is fundamentally inaccurate. No
social security funds are being stolen; the fund is making loans
and getting full interest on these loans. In this respect, the
social security fund is behaving just like any other prefunded
pension plan that invests in Treasury securities.
Although the system's financial
situation appears healthy, as we look ahead things change. The
system builds in a financial exercise in which the trustees--four
cabinet officers and two outside members--make actuarial forecasts
seventy-five years into the future. Seventy-five years is
obviously a long time, and these forecasts should by no means be
viewed as precise predictions. At the same time, given the
relatively predictable future demographics of the country--people
live reasonably predictable lifetimes, and the future size of the
labor force can be reasonably well forecast--these forecasts are
useful indicators of future imbalances.
Right now the forecasts indicate
that the system will continue to build its assets for another
twenty years and then run these assets down fairly sharply as the
huge baby boom population moves into retirement. System assets are
forecast to be exhausted in roughly 2035, and it would take an
immediate 2.6 percent increase in the combined employer-employee
payroll tax rate to extend the system's assets for the
seventy-five year forecasting period. Given the aging of the
population, the asset shortfall gets much more dramatic beyond
seventy-five years--the payroll tax increase necessary to finance
future benefits in perpetuity was most recently estimated at 7.7
percent. Viewed as a share of the overall economy, if no changes
are made, retirement and disability benefits are expected to rise
from 4.3 percent of total national output today to 7.3 percent of
total output by the end of the seventy-five year period, and to
higher levels further in the future. Perhaps more significantly,
when combined with a similar growth in Medicare, these types of
entitlement spending roughly double as a share of federal revenues
in the course of three decades, crowding out other types of
government spending or requiring new federal tax increases. These
indicators suggest that some changes should be made on the benefit
side.
There are many such changes. In
this talk I will not get into a full discussion of options. But if
changes are to be made on the benefit side, hence both improving
the trust fund finances and limiting the share of total output and
federal revenues used for entitlement spending, it is far, far
better to make the changes early rather than late. These
entitlement programs are retirement programs, which mean that
workers make their retirement plans based on an assumption of
benefits that will be available. It is widely viewed as unfair to
change benefits for present retirees who have already quit their
main job, and in fact important benefit cuts for retirees have
never been enacted in the whole sixty-year history of social
security. It is nearly as unfair to cut the benefits of workers
nearing retirement ages, for precisely the same reason. Hence, if
benefits are to be cut enough to matter, they should be cut in a
very gradual way, beginning early, and with the largest cuts in
store for the youngest workers for whom retirement is a long way
away and retirement planning is still very flexible. In this
sense, these future dates can be very misleading. While the system
might reasonably expect enough future revenues to pay the present
schedule of benefits until 2035, sensible changes in benefits
schedules should be enacted well before 2035. Very soon, in fact.
Rates of Returns
Since social security benefit payments are based on workers'
previous payroll tax contributions, it is possible to compute
implicit internal rates of return on these contributions. Many
years ago, the economist Paul Samuelson established that the
long-run equilibrium real return on a pay-as-you-go pension fund
of this sort would be equal to the trend rate of growth of real
wages plus the trend rate of growth of the labor force, roughly 1
percent according to present assumptions.
But these are equilibrium
returns. As the system builds to maturity, returns can be higher.
For example, workers born in the nineteenth century and retiring
in the early years of social security got much higher
returns--they received full benefits but with contributions paid
only from 1937 on. Workers born early in the twentieth century are
getting reasonable returns. For example, single workers born in
1920, earning average amounts of wage income and living normal
life spans, are receiving a real return on theirs and their
employer's social security contributions of nearly 3 percent,
roughly what would have been available in the bond market over
this period. In addition, because of the internal redistribution
in the system, lower-wage workers of any birth cohort get
higher-than-average returns. Workers of any birth cohort who die
early get lower-than- average returns. These differences are
conscious and, in fact, implicit in the social insurance structure
of the program.
But now that the program is
maturing, the inalterable mathematical logic of Samuelson's proof
is coming true, and implicit rates of return are dropping toward 1
percent. Whereas average income and life span workers born in 1920
received real returns essentially equal to those on government
bonds, average income and life span workers born now are expected
to receive real returns of about 1 percent, much below the likely
real return on bonds. High-income workers born now are even likely
to get negative returns.
Nothing can be done about these
basic profiles. The underlying math is incontrovertible. Moreover,
social security did pay out high financial returns to earlier
birth cohorts, effectively laying a further tax on younger and as
yet unborn workers. These younger workers may regret both the
underlying math and this tax, but they cannot change either. And
in terms of underlying social equity, these younger workers should
remember that they did not have to live through two world wars and
a depression, and that they are benefiting from the rising
productivity and living standards of the American economy. But it
is still true that if internal rates of return continue downward,
the basic political popularity of social security could at some
point be threatened.
This is why prefunding, or new
national saving, is so important. Any new funds devoted to the
retirement system can in effect be invested in new capital and can
pay at least the marginal real return on such funds, now roughly 4
percent if funds are invested in bonds and perhaps even more if
some funds are invested in equities. Moreover, new saving
represents a way to place some of the costs of future benefits on
those now in the workforce, who are already likely to receive
higher rates of return than will future cohorts. While returns are
inevitably dropping within the present system, new saving should
continue to pay high returns at the margin, and it represents a
fair way to pay for future benefit costs.
Here and Abroad
Before trying to develop solutions to these impending problems, we
should look abroad. As it happens, populations are aging around
the world, putting much pressure on foreign social security
systems. If anything, problems seem worse for most foreign
developed country systems than they do here.
The basic math in understanding
pension plans focuses on birth and death rates. If women have on
average more than 2.1 babies in their reproductive years,
populations expand and have a relatively high share of young
people. If women have on average less than 2.1 babies, populations
contract and have a relatively high share of old people. Then, as
mortality declines, the share of old people rises again, adding to
the phenomenon known as the aging of the population.
Around the world both fertility
and mortality rates are dropping in country after country.
Fertility rates are already well below 2.1 in most developed
countries and approaching 2.1 in most developing countries. Life
spans are already quite long in most developed countries and are
rising in most developing countries. The full social implications
of these trends are overwhelmingly positive. The drop in fertility
rates lowers population growth rates and takes pressure off the
world's resources, and the drop in death rates implies a generally
healthier and more productive workforce, with people permitted to
live into their retirement years to enjoy the fruits of their
labors. But while these trends are laudable and even exciting,
they do imply an overall aging of the world's population, and they
do put extra pressure on all national retirement systems that do
not prefund benefits.
As an indication of these
pressures, the twenty-two Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) countries with the most-developed economies
and social security systems had 18 percent of their population
over age sixty in 1990, with that share expected to grow to 31
percent by 2030. The share of population over age seventy-five,
the population group for which the social cost of care is much
higher, is expected to grow from 5 percent now to more than 10
percent by 2030. Similar trends are evident in the transitional
socialist countries of Eastern Europe and in China, Latin America,
Asia, and even Africa, though the less developed regions start
with smaller shares of their populations in the higher age groups.
The result of this aging of the
population, around the world as in the United States, is a growing
share of the economy devoted to paying for public pension
spending. The forecast share rises to more than 15 percent of
total output by 2030 for the OECD countries (more than double the
ratio for the United States), to nearly 15 percent for the
transitional socialist countries and China, and to nearly 10
percent for Latin America and the rest of Asia.
Most countries have yet to deal
with their looming pension system problems, but a few have. The
United Kingdom, Australia, and several Latin American countries,
most notably Chile, have all gone to systems that feature basic
flat benefits and then prefunded individual accounts on top of
that. What usually gets attention is the fact that these countries
have partly privatized their pension systems, but I would like to
focus on the fact that these countries have partly prefunded their
systems. In so doing, they have directly provided for some of
their future pension costs. They may have also generally raised
their national saving, realizing a high marginal rate of return,
and they could reap the benefits of a higher general standard of
living down the road. While the United States begins with lower
future financial costs of its aging society than is the case in
most other developed countries, and may not want to replicate
these other pension plans, it could well consider moving in the
direction of prefunding benefit payments.
Solutions
Many solutions have been proposed to this interrelated set of
social security problems. To keep the discussion manageable, I
will focus on four basic approaches--one based on the normal
twentieth-century response, two representing present political
opinion in Washington, and one that I proposed earlier in the
report of the 1994-96 Social Security Advisory Council. Though as
I said above, one can make very good arguments for at least a slow
trimming of the growth of benefits over time, the proposals are
very much alike in that each preserves in essential form the
present system of benefits. Each also preserves the present set of
social protections, the first objective I described. Further, each
tries to restore the long-run actuarial solvency of the social
security trust fund. The proposals differ in their economic
dimensions--whether they prefund some future benefit costs,
whether they raise national saving and take advantage of the
higher marginal return on this new saving, and whether they
increase payroll tax rates.
The standard twentieth-century
solution to the financial problems posed by an aging society was
to raise payroll taxes. Were this to be done now, these payroll
taxes would be invested in government securities and would yield
interest down the road. The combination of future taxes and future
interest returns would pay for the rising future benefit costs.
Under present actuarial estimates, an immediate 2.6 percent
increase in the combined payroll tax rate is necessary to finance
the present benefit schedule for the next seventy-five years; an
immediate 7.7 percent increase is necessary to finance the benefit
schedule in perpetuity.
Although this approach is a
simple and straightforward way to lower consumption and raise
national saving, it is not altogether appealing. For economists,
it introduces the issue of tax-rate distortions. As marginal tax
rates increase, incentives for people to work and be productive
could be reduced. Social security taxes may not operate like other
taxes in this regard, because people do get the money back, albeit
with some redistribution. Moreover, while going from 12.4 percent
to 15 percent may not seem terribly significant, we must remember
that the overall ratio of federal taxes to national output is
about 20 percent now, and this increase will come on top of these
other taxes. The cost of tax distortions is usually felt to depend
on the square of marginal tax rates, and 22.6 percent squared is
one-fourth more than 20 percent squared. Moreover, tax rates
cannot be raised forever. At some point, every country with an
aging population has to get off what we might call the tax and
spend treadmill. Indeed, the main reason that impending tax
burdens look less onerous for the United States than for other
countries is that in the past the United States has held the line
better against tax and benefit increases. Finally, for what it is
worth, tax increases are a political anathema: At this point, no
politician of either party would give this approach even passing
consideration.
In the set of recommendations
accompanying the report of the 1994-96 Advisory Council, I tried
to come up with an alternative way to raise national saving.
Instead of raising payroll tax rates, I suggested what I thought
might be a more popular approach of mandatory individual accounts
held on top of social security. Since individuals would own these
accounts, they might not think of them as tax increases. Moreover,
individuals would be free to invest these funds in a constrained
set of stock and bond index funds, much as happens today in
employer-controlled defined-contribution private pension accounts.
Even if the investments were confined to bonds, their return would
be much higher than present payroll contributions to the
pay-as-you-go system. Permitting stock market investments as well
would allow individuals to take advantage of what until now have
been greater returns on stocks than on bonds, though as I argue
below, these differential returns on equities may not be as great
in the future as they have been in the past.
However, it would cost social
security more to administer a system of individual accounts than
to administer the present system. Since the accounts would be
separate from the social security trust fund, there would also
need to be some gradual cuts in the growth of benefits over time
to bring the trust fund into long-term actuarial balance. These
could be done in a way that focuses on high-income individuals and
leaves low-wage and disability benefits largely intact. I designed
the combination of the returns from the individual accounts and
the benefit cuts to leave overall future retirement payments
roughly constant.
But mandatory add-on individual
accounts did not prove highly popular, and there have been several
attempts to ease the political pain. The National Commission on
Retirement Policy suggested a similar approach, but with the
individual accounts "carved out" of the present payroll
tax. Advantages and disadvantages of this system are similar to
those of the plan I recommended, with the significant exceptions
that the National Commission's plan would not have increased
saving now, and in the long run would have cut overall retirement
benefits.
In his 1999 budget message, the
President also suggested an approach that might be more palatable
politically. He proposed voluntary saving accounts (now called
Retirement Saving Accounts) that would carry a tax subsidy and be
matched. The voluntary accounts would be available only to
lower-income workers, who now have the lowest levels of pension
saving. But, at the same time, voluntary is voluntary. Only about
one-quarter of all low-income households now use freely available
tax-subsidized Individual Retirement Accounts, and only about 40
percent use 401(k) plans that carry a tax subsidy and are also
matched by employers. Unlike mandatory accounts, this voluntary
approach would not ensure that all underfunded workers looking at
reductions in their retirement standard of living would choose to
contribute to the new individual accounts. For the same reason,
this and other voluntary measures might raise national saving
relatively little.
In the same 1999 budget message,
President Clinton also proposed two measures to deal with the
actuarial problems of the social security trust fund. Rather than
raising payroll taxes, he would have made transfers of general
federal revenues to the social security trust fund. If these
transfers were not made from new borrowing, they would effectively
finance added benefit costs through higher federal taxes or lower
government spending than would otherwise be the case. Provided
that there were offsetting cuts in the general government budget,
these transfers should raise national saving, just as would higher
payroll taxes. At the same time, the same considerations suggest
that there could be some added tax distortions.
Transferring general revenues
would imply that for the first time revenues from outside normal
trust fund sources would be used to finance social security
benefit payments. There is nothing intrinsically wrong with
broadening the tax base beyond the payroll tax, but there is a
potential problem in breaching the trust fund limits. Until now
the social security trust fund has been self-financing. The
present value of all present and future benefit payments equals
the value of existing stocks of assets plus the present value of
present and future tax revenues. This long-run budget constraint
has presumably limited benefit payments. If general revenue
transfers were to be introduced, it might become much harder to
limit these transfers in the future. This could be a backdoor way
of putting the social security system on just the tax-and-spend
treadmill that politicians are trying to avoid and that many other
countries have not avoided.
The President also proposed to
invest some of social security's assets directly in common stock
index funds instead of government securities. This reinvestment
plan raises several new issues. First, unlike the add-on
individual accounts proposed above, this would be equity
investment without underlying new saving. As such, it would
represent only a transfer of wealth with the private sector, not a
creation of new national wealth. Second, since the central fund,
and not individuals, would own the equities, the direct government
ownership of common stock might threaten normal
business-government separations. Third, as with the individual
accounts, one can ask whether future returns to equities will
continue to exceed those on bonds. There is no doubt that stocks
have outperformed bonds in the past, but at this point
earnings-price ratios on stocks have been driven close to real
interest rates on bonds, in the view of many financial experts
providing inadequate compensation for the greater risk on stocks.
In this sense, it may not make sense to extrapolate past
differential returns on stocks. For whatever reason, the President
later withdrew the equity reinvestment part of his approach.
In response to the President's
plan, congressional Republicans produced one of their own. Instead
of having the government make the investment in common stocks, the
Republicans created small-scale individual accounts by diverting
revenue from the normal payroll tax. The money would go into
individual accounts, but with a twist. Individuals would choose
how to invest the funds, with government constraints on the type
of investments and even on the share that could be invested in
equities. Returns from the funds would in effect be owned by
social security. If the invested funds did not yield benefits as
high as social security, individuals would be guaranteed their
normal social security benefits, and the social security trust
fund would keep all returns from the individual accounts. If the
funds yielded more than social security, individuals would get
their normal social security benefits and could keep the extra. If
the stock investments do outperform government bonds, there could
be enough saving in normal social security benefits that the
actuarial soundness of the trust fund could be ensured.
These quasi-private accounts
also raise a number of issues. First, as with the other stock
investment plans, will future differential returns on equities
hold up? If not, the plan may not resolve the long-run actuarial
problems of the social security trust fund. Second, if the social
security trust fund is in effect guaranteeing the performance of
individuals' investments, in the sense of paying at least the same
benefits that individuals would have otherwise received, does it
really make sense to allow the individuals to choose the
investments? Even under the tight investment constraints,
individuals may gamble, given their complete safety net. Third, as
a political matter, if these individual accounts are described as
individual accounts, would it in fact be possible for the
government to take back all returns up to the normal benefit
levels of social security? Such a "clawback," as it has
become known, might be viewed as unwarranted government taxation.
Very often schemes such as this result in arrangements in which
private investors get the gains and the government picks up the
losses.
There are clear differences
among these competing approaches, though not so clear that
compromises seem out of the question. One central issue is that of
equity investment: How profitable will it be in the future, as
opposed to the past? Will it be profitable enough to account for
the greater risk on stocks? And, if it is done, should it be done
through individually owned accounts or through central fund
investment? Individual accounts are more expensive to run, and
they may at some point fray the political compromise underlying
social security--a general program benefiting all. At the same
time, they also avoid other political problems that may result
from central fund equity investment, if the government becomes a
huge, and perhaps the largest, stockholder for most American
corporations.
Then there is the national
saving issue, which I think is central. And here is a potential
pitfall--the approaches with the most political popularity may
also be those with the least effect on national saving. The least
popular approach involves payroll tax increases to prefund
benefits. The mandatory add-on individual accounts have also not
proven very popular and also clearly involve new saving. Switching
to voluntary individual accounts may be a reasonable political
compromise, but it also involves much less new saving. Covering
the actuarial deficit by general revenue financing should raise
national saving, at least if the non-social security portion of
the federal budget is suitably altered, but it may simultaneously
weaken fiscal discipline. And it, too, has not proven popular.
Carving the individual accounts out of existing payroll taxes may
also represent a political compromise, but it also does not raise
national saving.
Conclusion
Social security has been a huge success in the twentieth century,
arguably the largest and most popular social program the
government has ever adopted. Its reach is now nearly universal, it
has pulled millions of aged individuals out of poverty, and it
forms a retirement safety net for virtually all Americans.
The history of social security
in the twentieth century has been one of program growth--of tax
rates, benefit levels, and coverage levels. But times are
changing. At this point the system is nearing maturity and is
confronted with a new problem--the massive aging of the U.S.
population. We could respond to this population aging, and
attendant rise in payroll tax rates necessary to pay for future
benefits, by further increases in payroll tax rates, as was the
case throughout most of the twentieth century. Or we could try
some new approaches, such as add-on individual accounts, general
revenue transfers, or various mechanisms for investing in
equities. All of these can, in principle, pay for the presently
scheduled level of future benefits and preserve the actuarial
soundness of the social security trust fund. But only some of them
imply new national saving, the high rates of return on this new
saving, and new investments in American productivity. Our hardest
job now is to find reform measures that really generate this new
saving.