This is a conference on fiscal
policy, specifically on how to allocate any potential future
surpluses among debt reduction, tax cuts, and spending increases.
The question you and I might be asking right now is: What is a
monetary policymaker doing here? You know, of course, that I
always enjoy visiting with my fellow NABE members. But what
contribution can I make to this important topic?
My assignment is to answer this
question: How do the prevailing surplus and, especially, decisions
about the allocation of future potential surpluses affect the
formulation and conduct of monetary policy? The best way to
understand the issues involved, in my view, is through the concept
of the policy mix. Using this concept will allow us to focus on
the implications of alternative combinations of monetary and
fiscal policies--yielding the same level of aggregate demand--for
the real interest rate, the composition of output, and the current
account balance. And it also will help us understand the key
source of the interdependence of monetary and fiscal policy
decisions.
In planning my remarks today, I
intended first to discuss the analytics and the politics of the
policy mix and then to illustrate the power of the analysis by
using it to explain some of the important features of our current
experience. For example, the swing in the structural budget
balance clearly helps to explain the increase in the national
saving rate and the high level of investment relative to GDP in
this expansion. However, other important features of recent
macroeconomic experience--specifically the absence of a large
decline in real interest rates and the significant deterioration
in the current account balance--appear at least superficially
inconsistent with the predictions from the standard analytics.
One problem, I believe, is the
assumption that the recent dramatic swing in the structural budget
balance has been driven exclusively by policy. Perhaps even more
important are other developments that have affected real interest
rates and the current account balance over the same period. I
could sum up these problems by noting that "ceteris"
aren't always "paribus."
I conclude by discussing the
implications for monetary policy of options for the allocation of
the "potential" surplus. Because these options involve
alternative policies, the standard framework should provide
appropriate guidance about projected outcomes--ceteris paribus, of
course. I focus on two ways in which fiscal policy choices could
affect monetary policy. First, fiscal policy choices will affect
the interest rate consistent with full employment and price
stability. Second, a gradual reduction and ultimate retirement of
the federal government debt would require changes in the way
monetary policy is implemented.
The Analytics of the Policy
Mix
The policy mix is a very useful device for understanding the
interaction of monetary and fiscal policies. There are infinite
combinations of monetary and fiscal policies that yield the same
level of aggregate demand. The different combinations result in
different outcomes for the level of real interest rates, the
composition of output, and the current account balance. The
composition of output at a given time has implications for the
level of output over time. So the policy mix has quite important
implications for macroeconomic performance.
The policy mix can be easily
represented in a simple IS-LM diagram, shown in figure
1 (6 KB). This illustrates a simple model of macroeconomic
general equilibrium. The IS curve shows the combinations of
interest rate (R) and output (Y) consistent with equilibrium in
the output market. The LM curve shows the combinations of interest
rate and output consistent with equilibrium in the market for
money. The intersection of the curve shows the unique combination
of the interest rate and output consistent with equilibrium in all
markets simultaneously.
Let's start from a simple case
in which the level of capacity is given at a moment in time and
the intersection of IS and LM curves determines the prevailing
level of aggregate demand. As long as this intersection occurs at
or to the left of the capacity limit, potential output (Y*), it
determines the level of output, at least in the short run. I will
assume that the intersection takes place at potential output, so
that the outcome is consistent with the broad objectives of
monetary policy: price stability and full employment. Evaluating
alternative fiscal policies at an unchanged level of output--and
specifically at potential output--also allows us to abstract from
cyclical changes in the deficit and thereby to focus exclusively
on changes in the structural budget balance.
The position of the LM curve is
determined in part by the stance of monetary policy. I have drawn
the conventional upward sloping LM curve predicated on a constant
money stock. In this case, we could view the level of the money
stock as being adjusted by open market operations to be consistent
with the Federal Reserve's target for the interest rate.
Alternatively, we could draw the LM curve as a horizontal line at
the prevailing interest rate target set by the FOMC. The position
of the IS curve is determined in part by fiscal policy, including
the level of discretionary spending and benefit and tax rates. The
latter rates also affect the slope of the IS curve, but I will
abstract from that detail.
In Figure
1 (6 KB), I depict two of the infinite number of combinations
of IS and LM curves that intersect at potential output--the
intersection at B corresponding to a looser fiscal and tighter
monetary policy than the intersection at A.
The first question I want to
answer is, What difference does it make where the intersection of
IS and LM curves occurs for a given level of output? The answer
is, It makes a world of difference. A combination of tighter
fiscal and looser monetary policy (point A compared with point B
in figure
1 (6 KB)) implies a lower interest rate, a higher share of
investment (and, in general, of interest-sensitive components of
spending) in GDP, a lower value of the dollar, and a higher level
of net exports and hence of the current account surplus.
Therefore, by selecting a particular policy mix, policymakers can
affect the amount of capital formation and the current account
balance.
The above simple version of the
IS-LM model does not begin to do justice to the topic. In more
sophisticated models, we would see explicitly the long-run
increase in output associated with a shift in the composition of
output today toward more investment. In addition, more
sophisticated models would also show explicitly the increase in
the exchange rate and the associated decline in the current
account balance in response to a policy mix that resulted in
higher real interest rates. Finally, more sophisticated models
could also take into account a second dimension of fiscal policy
changes. Not only do changes in tax rates and spending affect
aggregate demand, they can also affect aggregate supply, for
example, when they alter after-tax wage rates and after-tax rates
of return to saving and investment. The effect of any change in
the policy mix will also be affected by supply-side incentives
incorporated in the fiscal part of the mix.
The Politics of the Policy
Mix: Does Monetary Policy Respond to Fiscal Policy?
How does the choice about the policy mix get made? An interesting
question! No, we do not have a joint committee on the policy mix
that considers the benefits of alternative mixes and reaches a
judgment. The policy mix is determined by sequential
decisionmaking, subject to an understanding of the structure of
the economy and of the likely responses of the other policymakers
to one's policy actions.
In my view, the process works as
follows. The Administration and the Congress together make
decisions that determine the fiscal part of the policy mix. Over
the last 20 years, these decisions generally have been based on
considerations that have more to do with long-run objectives such
as promotion of higher longer-term growth, than with short-run
stabilization. Making these decisions takes considerable time
because of the dynamics of the annual budget process and the
legislative process. The current year's decisions are incorporated
and the following years' decisions are anticipated in the fiscal
policy assumptions underlying the Federal Reserve's forecast,
extending out a year or two. The Federal Reserve then sets its
policy to achieve the broad objectives assigned to it,
specifically, price stability and full employment. Fiscal
decisions are, in turn, affected by budget forecasts that are
partly contingent on monetary policy assumptions.
In effect, fiscal policymakers
make the fundamental decision about the policy mix. Monetary
policymakers smooth the transition to the new equilibrium, by
minimizing the effect on output relative to full employment and on
prices. Because monetary policy adjusts continuously to changes in
the economy, including those resulting from fiscal policy, it
makes sense to think that fiscal policy decisions are made first
and monetary policy decisions are conditional on the fiscal
decisions.
So does this mean that monetary
policy responds directly to fiscal policy actions? I believe it is
more accurate to say that the Fed's response is indirect. That is,
monetary policy responds to changes in fiscal policy in much the
same way that it responds to other influences on the economy, such
as equity prices, exchange rates, or the demand for U.S. exports
due to changed growth prospects abroad. Each and all of these
developments affect both the macroeconomic developments and the
forecast that drive adjustments in monetary policy in pursuit of
full employment and price stability.
It is also important not to
overstate the role monetary policy plays in shaping the policy
mix. Indeed, the fiscal policy decision uniquely determines the
policy mix. In terms of our diagram, the game is fundamentally
over when the fiscal decision pins down the intersection of the IS
curve and the vertical line at full employment. The only question
remaining is how the LM curve will come to intersect at the same
point.
One possibility, of course, is
that the Federal Reserve adjusts its open market operations to
move the interest rate to this point. In a regime in which the Fed
implements policy by choosing a target for the money stock, either
the money stock could be adjusted to move the LM curve to this
point, or price flexibility would ultimately get the job done,
with the emphasis on the ultimately. The role of active monetary
policy is to avoid the need for price flexibility--that is, to
prevent the fiscal decision from either temporarily lowering
output below its full employment level or permanently increasing
prices.
In an interest-rate regime,
holding the funds rate unchanged following a shift in the IS curve
would result in an escalating disequilibrium. For this reason, an
interest-rate regime has to be modeled in terms of a policy
reaction function. Under a plausible policy rule--for example,
utilizing actual or forecast output gaps and inflation rates--the
interest rate would be reset over time until it was consistent
with the intersection of the IS curve and the vertical line at
potential output and price stability.
The message of such an interest
rate rule is that monetary policy responds only indirectly to
fiscal policy. That is, the rule specifies the adjustment of the
interest rate to changes in output and prices (the indirect
approach), not the adjustment to changes in tax rates or spending
(as would be the case in a direct approach). However, if we look
at the reduced form equation for the now endogenous monetary
policy instrument, we shall, to be sure, find--lurking on the
right-hand side--the exogenous components of the fiscal policy
decision--the level of discretionary spending and the benefit and
tax rates. That the response may be indirect does not make it any
less systematic.
In the "real world,"
of course, many factors besides fiscal policy are likely to be
affecting inflation and output. So we may rarely actually observe
the interrelationships implied by the analytics of the policy mix.
That is, ceteris are rarely paribus, which brings me to my next
topic.
Comparing the Theoretical
Prediction to Recent Experience
The swing from budget deficit to surplus has been much more
dramatic than was expected when the fiscal year 1994 budget was
adopted. Such a dramatic swing in the budget balance might have
been expected to yield a particularly dramatic confirmation of the
predictions of the analytic model, in the form of a sharp decline
in real interest rates and a significant improvement in the
current account balance.
In fact, during the period of a
dramatic swing in the budget balance, real interest rates have not
declined, and the current account balance has significantly
deteriorated. If you hadn't already suspected, we are about to
find out that the real world is always more complex, and much more
interesting, than our simple models. Two explanations for this
conflict between theoretical prediction and recent experience are
possible. First, the preceding analysis is fundamentally flawed.
Second, it is at least incomplete. I will take the second route
and argue that the problem was that ceteris were not paribus in
this episode.
Ceteris paribus, of course,
means "all other things being equal." In our models, it
is a way of examining the effect of one shock, holding constant
all other shocks that could effect the variables in question. In
class and in model simulations, we can always impose ceteris
paribus. Indeed, ceteris paribus was implicitly assumed all the
way through the section on analytics. In the real world, we do not
have this option. In addition, in the analytics, by holding output
fixed at potential, we abstracted from the effect of cyclical
influences on the budget balance, on interest rates, and on the
current account.
The key to getting the right
answer in the analysis is to identify correctly the multiple
shocks that induced the swing in the ratio of deficit to GDP and
that affected the real interest rate and current account, as well
as to take into account the effect of the cyclical developments. I
assumed in the analytics of the policy mix that that any
non-cyclical change in the deficit was due to a change in
policy--some combination of increases in tax rates and cutbacks in
government spending. Indeed, specific fiscal policy actions make
this characterization appear qualitatively correct. But to explain
the real-world outcomes we also have to allow for the role of
other influences, specifically structural change.
A portion of the swing in the
budget balance was of course due to the cyclical upswing. In our
analytics, we were able to control for this by holding the level
of output constant at potential output. But to apply this to our
dynamic economy, we have to allow for uncertainty about the level
of potential output at a given time and the growth in potential
output over time.
A unique feature of the recent
cyclical experience has been the divergence between the cyclical
strength of the U.S. economy and that of its major trading
partners--that is, the weak expansion in Europe, the long period
of stagnation in Japan, and the crises among many emerging market
economies from late 1997 through 1998. This divergence in cyclical
strength was accompanied for several years during this episode by
a persistent appreciation of the dollar, further contributing to a
deterioration in the current account.
However, the more serious
problem with the application of the conventional framework is the
failure to account for structural change, specifically a decline
in the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) and
an increase in trend growth. The decline in the NAIRU, for
example, would raise the equilibrium level of output and increase
imports, worsening the current account balance. More rapid trend
income growth would also increase the growth of imports and hence
cause a deterioration in the current account. In addition, higher
trend productivity growth, driven by an increase in the
profitability of investing in new technology, would raise the
equilibrium real interest rate and encourage capital flows to the
United States to take advantage of higher returns on capital. This
in turn would lead to an appreciation of the dollar, further
augmenting the current account deficit. Once again, it appears
that the increase in the economy's trend rate of productivity
growth is playing a starring role in our explanation of recent
macroeconomic developments.
In discussing the interaction
between the swing in the federal budget and the increase in the
productivity trend, I have focused on how the latter may have
offset the tendency of the former to lower real interest rates.
But, of course, the interaction works in both directions. The
increase in the equilibrium real interest rate, expected as a
result of an increase in the productivity trend, is also a ceteris
paribus result. It depends critically on the assumed fiscal policy
rule. For example, if tax rates are constant and government
spending remains a constant share of GDP, then the higher
productivity trend will, in general, yield a higher equilibrium
real interest rate. However, if real (or nominal) government
spending is held constant, the surplus will rise over time as a
share of GDP, putting downward pressure on the equilibrium real
rate, offsetting, at least in part, the effect on the real rate of
the higher trend productivity.
The Surplus Conundrum and the
Policy Mix
Although the discussion of the policy mix did not fully explain
recent economic performance, I still believe it offers important
insights into the alternative options for dealing with the current
and projected surpluses, at least if ceteris really turn out to be
paribus. But the recent episode underscores the difficulty of
actually predicting real interest rates and the current account
when unknowable shocks will surely intervene along the way.
My assignment is not to evaluate
how much confidence we should have in projected surpluses or to
assess the merits of alternative allocations of projected
surpluses. Rather, my assignment is to connect fiscal and monetary
policy decisions. I have emphasized the value of evaluating fiscal
policy options in models that incorporate reasonable monetary
policy reaction functions. Doing so builds in the indirect
response of monetary policy to fiscal policy changes, consistent
with the logic of the policy mix. This is, in effect, the approach
I followed my discussion of the analytics of the policy mix by
assuming that monetary policy is reset--albeit indirectly--in
response to a change in fiscal policy.
Retaining the projected
non-social security surplus in the CBO baseline is one
alternative. The other options involve increased fiscal stimulus
and, as a result, will be accompanied, ceteris paribus, by a
higher equilibrium real interest rate in the long run. They would
also likely result in a lower share of investment in output and a
higher current account deficit than the option that preserves
higher surpluses. The specific outcomes will depend on the
details, especially on the nature of supply-side incentives in any
spending or tax changes. Ceteris paribus, monetary policy--run off
a sensible reaction function--will end up validating the higher
equilibrium real interest rate, to keep prices from accelerating
indefinitely.
The Implications of Debt
Retirement for Monetary Policy Operations
One additional consequence of the choice among these options is
that preserving the surpluses would lead to a gradual decline in
and ultimately the retirement of the federal government debt. The
prospects for such an outcome depend, of course, on the realized
growth rate of income and hence tax revenue and one's assumption
about the starting base of expenditures and the appropriate
baseline for its rate of growth. I have already noted that such an
outcome should not be viewed as a foregone conclusion. And, even
if the Treasury debt were to be fully retired, that outcome would
be likely to be transitory. Once the baby boomers begin to retire,
the social security trust fund will be progressively run down, and
at some point, the overall budget will likely move from surplus to
deficit again.
Today, Treasury securities
account for the bulk of the Federal Reserve's portfolio of assets.
Treasury securities are a convenient and natural choice for the
Federal Reserve's portfolio because they pose no credit risk and
because the depth and liquidity of the Treasury market facilitate
open market operations. Although the Treasury market has been the
traditional vehicle for monetary policy operations in recent
decades, the Federal Reserve Act provides authority for the
Federal Reserve to purchase a fairly wide range of other
assets--including obligations of federal agencies, certain
obligations of state and local governments, foreign exchange, and
sovereign debt. Moreover, the Federal Reserve often supplies
reserves through repurchase transactions in addition to outright
purchases. If the Treasury market became less liquid, we could
substitute longer-term RPs against eligible collateral for some
outright purchases of securities. If the existing classes of
assets that the Federal Reserve is authorized to purchase or to
acquire were deemed too narrow, we could pursue technical changes
in the Federal Reserve Act to authorize transactions with a
broader range of assets. Still another option would be to expand
the role of the discount window in the provision of reserves to
the banking system. The key point is that declining Treasury debt
does not pose any insurmountable long-term problem for the Federal
Reserve. There would, of course, be transitional issues as
monetary policy operations adapted. But we surely maintain the
effectiveness of our monetary policy operations. So a decision
about whether or not to hold on to the surpluses and ultimately
retire the government debt should not be affected by any concern
that this option might undermine the effectiveness of monetary
policy.
Some have been concerned that
the Federal Reserve and the Treasury might be working at cross
purposes today to the extent that reductions in the Treasury debt
supply have lead to declines in longer-term Treasury rates at a
time when monetary policy is aiming to slow the pace of economic
activity to a more sustainable rate. To date, the main impact of
Treasury operations and debt management prospects has been on
longer-term Treasury rates, with only a small spillover effect on
the financial variables that affect private spending
decisions--short- and longer-term private interest rates, equity
prices, and exchange rates. To the extent that Treasury debt
management operations affect the private interest rates or other
financial conditions that matter for private spending decisions,
the FOMC can always adjust its policy settings as appropriate to
achieve its objectives.
Conclusion
In debt management as well as other fiscal policy decisions, the
Administration and the Congress should make the decisions that are
in the best long-run interest of the economy. Monetary policy
cannot affect the long-run consequences of such policy decisions,
but it can adjust to smooth the economy's transition to the new
equilibrium. Monetary and fiscal policies should therefore be
thought of as working as partners, rather than in competition with
each other. In addition, decisions about the allocation of the
government surplus or about debt management operations should not
be limited by any concern that a gradual decline in or even
ultimate retirement of the government debt would undermine the
ability of monetary policy to achieve the broad objectives that
the Congress has assigned to it.