Thank you very much for giving me
the opportunity to join this illustrious group of economists in
this historic setting. The end of one year and start of another is
a natural time to focus on accomplishments and also to list the
things to do or to understand better. In this spirit, I would like
to review last year's economic performance and then raise some
topics related to the underpinnings of macroeconomics and monetary
policy.
Of course, the views that I am
about to express are my own and do not necessarily reflect those
of other members of the FOMC or the Board of Governors.
Economic Performance in 1999
Last year presented various challenges for monetary policymakers.
Domestic demand was particularly strong, led by consumption
expenditures, which grew 5� percent last year. However,
consumption was only one engine driving the spectacular
performance of 1999. Business fixed investment, paced by spending
on producers' durable equipment, also rose strongly--by 7 percent.
One investment sector, the housing sector, which had been a source
of considerable strength in 1998, grew less rapidly last year.
Although single-family starts rose further in 1999, starts of
multifamily units were off from their 1998 pace.
Long-term interest rates trended
downward in early 1999 but more than retraced those declines by
the end of the year. Equity prices rose over much of 1999, raising
the value of household assets and improving the general sense of
financial well-being of our citizens as well as lowering the cost
of capital faced by businesses.
Recovery in Asia, with perhaps
the apparent exception of Japan, and a pick-up in growth in Europe
accompanied this good news in the United States. During the first
half of 1998, net exports subtracted almost 1� percentage points
from GDP growth. With conditions improving overseas, the external
sector subtracted less than � percentage point from growth in the
second half of 1999.
Throughout 1999, the Federal
Open Market Committee took action to maintain balance in the
economy. The sense of the FOMC was that the tightening of labor
markets that accompanied a growth of demand exceeding even the
stepped-up pace of supply growth would likely create upward
pressures on labor costs and eventually on the rate of price
inflation. Accordingly, we moved preemptively, raising rates 75
basis points in three increments. This tightening reversed the
easings that had been put in place during the second half of 1998
in response to the market turmoil, including in the U.S. markets,
triggered by the unexpected events in Russia. As you well know,
rates were raised another 25 basis points at our meeting earlier
this month.
At the February meeting, the
FOMC also abandoned the approach of discussing "biases"
regarding interest rate movements, which seemed to engender overly
strong reactions or a misreading of our intentions from markets.
Instead, the FOMC adopted the approach of discussing our views on
economic developments and potential risks to good economic
performance. Using this new approach, the FOMC earlier this month
indicated a concern that risks were weighted mainly toward
conditions that might lead to increased inflation.
Sources of Performance
Four major forces provide the underpinning for the vigorous
domestic growth we are currently experiencing. The first is the
creation of, and massive investment in, information and
communications technology. This capital spending, along with the
apparent technological improvements, is thought to have been
important in the increase in productivity--the output of goods and
services per hour of work--that is currently providing such
momentum for the economy of the United States. The second major
force is business deregulation. The removal of unnecessary
government regulation started more than twenty years ago, during
the administration of President Gerald Ford, and gathered momentum
during the Carter years. It has altered the business landscape.
Deregulation allowed, indeed forced, businesses to focus more
clearly on a market place that has become more competitive, with
fewer constraints and increased flexibility. The third major force
is a more prudent fiscal policy. The 1990s were characterized by a
movement of federal government balances toward and then into
surplus, which, many believe, has freed up resources for
private-sector investment.
The final major force is the
reduction of both actual and expected inflation. Relatively stable
prices have allowed businesses and households to plan their
economic affairs with an expectation that the value of investments
will not be eroded through a pernicious and uncertain increase in
the general price level. Indeed, relative price level stability
has reinforced the impetus provided by deregulation for businesses
to manage their affairs with a priority on efficiency.
Observations and Open Issues:
Resource Utilization
Against this backdrop, I want to raise some issues where further
progress is needed if we are to understand recent macroeconomic
events better. Some of these issues have been of concern for some
time, and a few are new.
The first issue I wish to raise
involves the supply side of the economy and grows out of the
recent, unusual conjuncture of rapid growth and high resource
utilization with low and stable inflation. What is the proper
measurement of resource tightness? The two most prominent measures
of resource tightness, capacity utilization in manufacturing and
the rate of unemployment, have historically moved fairly closely
together over the cycle. However, they have diverged in the past
several years, in part as the surge in investment has provided
considerable capacity to the manufacturing sector while labor
markets have become tighter and tighter. We need a better
understanding of the implications of this divergence and, in
particular, a clearer sense of which measure, or combination of
measures, of resource utilization best foreshadows the emergence
of price pressures.
A second, and related, issue is
whether the nature of "capacity" has changed. In the
1940s and 1950s, large-scale units of fixed machinery--such as
blast furnaces and assembly lines--more normally characterized
manufacturing capacity. Many observers have argued that, because
this capacity required long lead times to manufacture, test, and
install, available capacity was easier to measure and slower to
change. In such circumstances, high levels of capacity utilization
were good predictors of resource tightness, which was likely to
translate into pricing pressure. Now, we hear, capacity in
manufacturing is more technology intensive and can be adjusted
more easily to reflect supply and demand conditions. If true, this
relatively "elastic" supply of manufacturing capacity
would imply that capacity utilization may not become
"tight" by historical standards and our measure of
capacity utilization would therefore be a less-certain early
warning signal of potential pricing pressure. I have seen no proof
of the assertion that the nature of manufacturing capacity has
changed, although the experience of the last several years
suggests that it has.
A third related issue has to do
with the average workweek and labor force participation. During
this episode of strong growth, the average workweek has not
increased significantly. In 1994, the average workweek was about
34 � hours, and today it is about 34 � hours. This steadiness is
in part due to mix shifts, as the economy moves away from
manufacturing sector jobs, in which the forty-hour workweek is the
norm, to service sector jobs, in which shorter workweeks are more
common. Moreover, the labor force participation rate, while
fluctuating, has remained around 67 percent during this period.
Given the various other elements of evidence regarding labor
market tightness, including survey data on job market conditions
and the measured unemployment rate, I find it puzzling that both
the workweek and the labor force participation rate have not
increased more strongly. One theory, of course, is that household
wealth, to which I turn next, might limit the felt need by some
potential workers, presumably young people dependent on parents
and perhaps older citizens, to participate in the labor market.
Observations and Open Issues:
Equity Markets
Also of interest are valuations in equity markets, the role they
should play in policymaking, and whether old relationships have
changed. Many observers have asked if I think that the Federal
Reserve can or should have a fixed view on the proper level of
equity markets. Every time I consider this question, I come up
with the same answer: The Fed cannot target specific levels in
equity markets. Equity prices are set by the give-and-take of
supply and demand, with participants buying and selling based on
their own information that shapes their long-term expectations.
Investors can and should be influenced by several factors,
including expectations of corporate earnings, attractiveness of
alternative investments (both domestic and international), and
differing appetites for "ownership" risk as opposed to
"creditor" risk. I believe that the Federal Reserve's
tools--primarily short-term interest rates--are too blunt to
attempt to achieve specific levels of stock market valuations. I
also believe that policymakers should not necessarily attempt to
put their judgments of correct values above those of the market.
Simply put, equity prices should properly be thought of as a
relative price-the value of the existing capital stock relative to
that of goods. Central banks are not good at fine-tuning relative
prices. Rather, leave us the responsibility for determining the
policy that anchors the general price level in the long run.
However, equity markets do have
important spillover effects on the real economy. As you know,
economists often speak of the "wealth effect," and
econometric modeling indicates that consumers ultimately tend to
spend about three to four cents for every dollar increment to
wealth. In addition, consumer sentiment is tied to feelings of
financial well-being. Through both of these channels, the
so-called wealth effect and the more general influence on consumer
sentiment, equity valuations can and do affect consumption and
macroeconomic performance. Equity markets are also a significant
source of investment capital, and valuations in the stock market
are one determinant of the cost of capital for businesses.
Therefore, equity prices affect business fixed investment, a major
driver of our economy. Given the economic importance of equity
prices, it is reasonable for policymakers to monitor developments
in this market even if we do not "target" specific
values. We have seen in other economies that the bursting of
bubbles in financial markets can create unsettled conditions that
affect real economic activity. Therefore, the maintenance of sound
equity market conditions is of concern to policymakers, though how
that can be accomplished is often far from clear.
My questions about equity
markets center on the issue of valuation and the wealth effect.
Economists propose numerous approaches to determining the
"correct" level of equity prices. One such approach
compares equity market valuations (namely earnings-price ratios)
to the return on fixed-income securities, generally the ten-year
U.S. Treasury bond. But many observers have suggested that this
measure of the "correct" stock market valuation may no
longer be accurate. Some suggest that the nature of equity markets
has changed with the introduction of new instruments that allow
for the better management or sharing of risks. Therefore, these
observers assert that lower premiums over risk-free returns are
appropriate and that old relationships between earnings-price
ratios and the return on Treasury instruments no longer hold.
Others argue that, in this world of knowledge-intensive
industries, accounting treatments do not accurately measure true
economic earnings, and therefore measures of "correct"
stock valuations do not capture economic reality that market
participants see. These assertions are interesting, but they need
further investigation.
In addition, with respect to
proper valuations, we know that many businesses are using options
as a form of compensation to employees and that the value of these
options is not being recorded as compensation at the time they are
granted. We roughly estimate that accounting for the value of
options granted would have reduced reported income for S&P
1500 firms nearly 10 percent in 1998. The same adjustment would
have reduced the growth rate of reported income for S&P 1500
firms almost 2� percentage points per year, on average, during
the 1996-98 period. When looked at with these refinements, the
current earnings-price ratios appear even more out of alignment
with historical experience.
When one considers the
performance of the stock market during the recent past, it is
clear that the gains are not evenly distributed, even among stock
market investors. Some of the greatest beneficiaries of the
unprecedented generation of stock market wealth have been those
with the skills and the work style to work in high-tech companies,
who are rewarded with stock, and those with the courage to invest
in high-tech sectors. This observation leads to several questions.
First, how skewed is the distribution of gains from the stock
market? If gains are indeed skewed, what then is the actual
dynamic of the wealth effect? When does an unequal participation
in equities become sufficiently broad-based to influence the path
of our economy? I think of these questions as providing the
microeconomic underpinnings to our macroeconomic performance.
Finally, we have seen a run-up
in margin debt, particularly during the last two months of 1999
and the first month of 2000. I believe that the Federal Reserve
should not foster the impression that we are targeting the equity
market by adjusting our one tool in the margin area, namely
initial margin requirements. However, given our obvious interest
in macro-stability, it is useful to understand more fully what has
motivated this recent run-up in margin. Some argue that it
reflects a desire on the part of investors to capture some capital
gains, while others are quick to point out that, as a percentage
of market valuation, margin has not increased dramatically.
According to another theory, margin borrowing is the realm of the
small investor whereas large investors finance equity purchases
through other means. In any event, prudent margin procedures are
an important part of sound business practice. I expect that those
extending margin credit, especially the major clearing firms, as
well as investors, and the public at large, would continue to
recognize that conservative margin practices are in their own
interest.
Observations and Open Issues:
International Markets
Let me turn now to the role of international developments in
policy. Our mandate gives priority to price stability and maximum
sustainable employment, which I think are the right elements for
us to consider in policy deliberations. Therefore, I believe that
international economic considerations, like stock market
valuations, should receive only the focus merited because of their
implications for the U.S. economy. Certainly, developments in the
international sector, in particular a large and growing current
account deficit, might indicate that there are imbalances in the
economy of the United States. Similarly, movements in the exchange
value of the U.S. dollar might transmit pressures on inflation,
but they also are an important transmission mechanism for monetary
policy. However, managing the external balance and the exchange
value of the U.S. dollar is obviously not the goal of monetary
policy.
One important contribution to
the ongoing deterioration of our current account balance is the
tendency for U. S. residents, for reasons not fully understood by
economists, to have a higher propensity to import out of every
dollar of income than do residents in the countries that are our
major trading partners. This, of course, means that even
sustaining trend growth both in the United States and in our
trading partners will not necessarily close the trade gap. To do
so would require a period of sustained stronger-than-trend growth
overseas.
Many professional economists and
market observers now question the sustainability of our current
account deficit. I suggest that the combination of a large current
account deficit and a strong U.S. dollar is, in part, a reflection
of the relative attractiveness of the U.S. economy as a
destination for foreign capital. We are attracting savings from
abroad because we currently have a higher rate of return on
investment than many other countries do. This state of affairs, of
course, is a reflection of the factors that have given rise to
this long period of domestic prosperity. How much longer
prosperity can continue is obviously the key question. The answer
depends on the ability of businesses and workers in the United
States to continue to generate growing productivity increases.
Because few of us forecast the current period of investment-driven
productivity increases, it is difficult to predict when it will
end. We know only that, at some point, productivity will stop
accelerating. But the potential for change is not the exclusive
domain of the United States. The ability of other countries to
adjust their systems of production to take advantage of new
technologies will be an important determinant of when other
markets will offer returns that are comparable to those available
in the United States. I imagine that, seeing the gains that we
have experienced from our capital deepening, investors would look
for the earliest signs of a similar phenomenon in other countries.
The one lesson we can offer is that the configuration of
competitive and flexible markets, management focused on
shareholder value, and supportive macroeconomic conditions is not
achieved without costs in terms of some societal dislocations and
that configuration requires good fortune, sacrifice, and
discipline.
Conclusion
As you can see, these are interesting times in which to be a
central banker. This complex set of forces requires continued
vigilance on our part. Additionally, the last twenty-four months
have raised an important set of questions regarding measures of
real economic performance, the behavior of inflation, financial
market indicators, and the growing globalization of today's
economy. I highlighted some of these questions with you today. I
have enjoyed immensely having to grapple with these issues but
recognize that we at the central bank may have all of the right
questions but do not have all the answers.
Thank you for your attention.