Economic performance over
the past several years has been exceptional. The economy
is about to set a record for the longest expansion.
Economic growth has been proceeding at a rate that is
close to double what was generally viewed as the long-term
trend when this expansion began. Inflation remains modest,
despite a decline in the unemployment rate to levels that
many would have expected to trigger a significant
acceleration in prices.
But if you are a
forecaster or a policymaker, rather than an economic
historian, you must focus on the next chapter. The
fundamental question today, it seems to me, is whether the
current set of macroeconomic conditions--specifically, the
growth of output and the unemployment rate--is
sustainable--that is, consistent with stable, low
inflation. If it is, the expansion could continue on its
current path, unless disturbed by some shock or policy
mistake. Otherwise, the challenge for monetary policy is
to guide the economy to a sustainable path while
preserving low inflation.
This challenge is
heightened by the unusual degree of uncertainty about the
limits of capacity and potential growth, related in part
to ongoing structural changes in the economy. Concerns
have also been raised about potential imbalances in some
sectors, for example, about the sustainability of equity
prices, the personal saving rate, the current account
deficit, and debt burdens. These concerns about
sustainability and the challenges they pose for monetary
policy are the focus of my remarks this afternoon.
Let me remind you that,
as always, the views I express are my own. I am not
speaking on behalf of either the Board of Governors or the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Varieties of Landings
In figure
1, I present four plausible scenarios for future
growth. Each has a quite different implication for both
the outlook and policy. In each case the economy faces an
initial gap between actual output (the dashed line) and
potential output (the solid line). Such a gap is typical
of conditions that follow a recession. During the
expansion phase, at least for a period, growth in
production typically exceeds the growth in capacity, so
that the gap between actual and potential output is closed
gradually.
For the moment, I shall
focus exclusively on the concerns about sustainability
related to the balance between aggregate supply and
demand. Later I shall turn to concerns about imbalances in
equity prices, the personal saving rate, the current
account, and the household debt burden.
A Soft Landing
Figure 1.A depicts a soft landing scenario, the graceful
transition from the initial output gap to a sustainable
growth path at full employment. A soft landing occurs if,
as the level of output approaches potential, the growth of
actual output slows to the growth of potential output just
as actual output reaches potential. The line for potential
output is, in effect, the runway. The line for actual
output is like the path of a plane coming in for a soft
landing--at least if you stand on your head while looking
at the chart!
Steady inflation is
generally one of the signs of sustainability. A simple
model of inflation dynamics is that changes in inflation
are induced by excess aggregate demand or supply, as
reflected in the output gap. When actual output rises
above potential, according to this model, the resulting
excess aggregate demand leads to rising inflation.
In the short run, supply
shocks--including both relative price shocks and changes
in trend productivity--can also affect inflation dynamics.
But these effects are temporary. Ultimately, inflation
dynamics will be driven by the output gap. At some point
in any expansion, therefore, a soft landing is the
preferred path to preserve a healthy expansion. Such a
slowdown in growth is desirable because the alternative is
higher inflation--indeed, continually rising inflation.
Looking back, most recessions have resulted from attempts
by the policy authorities--yes, the Fed--to reverse
increases in inflation generated by overheating.
A Reverse Soft
Landing
Figure 1.B depicts an alternative scenario in which the
above-trend growth in the expansion phase has moved the
economy beyond the point of its sustainable capacity to
produce. Policymakers in this case failed to execute a
soft landing. What could they do in this case to best
ensure the continuation of a healthy expansion? The answer
is to engineer the closest possible approximation to a
soft landing, one in which we glide to potential beginning
from a position initially above rather than from below
potential. Because the convergence to potential is from
above rather than below, I call this a "reverse"
soft landing.
In this case, because
the economy is already operating beyond its sustainable
capacity, the economy may not be able to avoid some
acceleration in inflation as policymakers try to engineer
the soft landing. Therefore, the return to the potential
output path has to be achieved in a sufficiently timely
fashion to minimize any increase in inflation during the
transition. Also, in the reverse soft landing case, growth
must slow, not just to trend but to below trend in order
to close the output gap. As a result, the unemployment
rate must rise during the transition to full employment in
this case. Hence, whereas the soft landing outcome in
figure 1.A involves a stabilization of the unemployment
rate at its low point and of inflation near its recent
low, in the reverse soft landing case depicted in figure
1.B, both inflation and unemployment rates are likely to
rise during the transition.
The Best-Case
Scenario: Supply Meets Demand
The first two scenarios I have described assume that
demand has to adjust to a steady supply path to achieve
sustainability. There are natural equilibrating
mechanisms, as well as policy adjustments, that encourage
such adjustment in demand relative to supply. An
alternative scenario is that supply adjusts to demand.
This case is depicted in figure 1.C in which the growth of
potential increases just as output threatens to push
beyond potential. In this scenario, the runway has
fortuitously landed on the plane, as it were. If this
scenario describes the current episode, then the economy
can continue to grow at 4 percent, the unemployment rate
can remain near 4 percent, and inflation can remain steady
at its prevailing rate.
This scenario may seem
farfetched. But it has the advantage of incorporating the
role of supply-side as well as demand-side forces that
appear to be at work in this expansion, and it would at
least help explain the stability of inflation at
prevailing growth and unemployment rates. Indeed, a
possible decline in the NAIRU and, especially, an increase
in the growth rate of potential output appear to be
essential elements of this expansion. Still, even if we
take into account the supply-side changes, we should not
expect a perfect balancing between supply and demand.
The Worse-Case
Scenario: Hard Landings
The worst-case alternative to a soft landing, to continue
the analogy, is often referred to as a hard landing.
Despite, or perhaps because of, the recent exceptional
performance of the U.S. economy, some see a growing danger
of a hard landing.
A hard landing might
seem like an oxymoron. A crash is a crash, after all, not
a landing. But the key to a landing is that it is required
to ensure sustainability of an expansion. A soft landing
is the preferred course to ensuring a healthy, sustainable
expansion, if it can be executed. A reverse soft landing
is the second-best option. Otherwise, a hard landing may
be unavoidable, despite the best efforts of policymakers.
The upside of a hard landing is that it contributes to
reversing imbalances and, afterwards, allows policymakers
to aim once again at achieving a healthy, sustainable
expansion, ultimately combining full employment, maximum
sustainable growth, and price stability.
It is useful to
distinguish two broad classes of hard landings. The first
involves the reversal of an imbalance between aggregate
supply and aggregate demand. The classic example is the
boom-bust scenario. The second class involves the
unwinding of sector or market imbalances that either
initiate a downturn in the economy or aggravate a downturn
that would otherwise have occurred. A classic example of
this genre is a stock market correction. I will focus
first on the boom-bust scenario to complete my
classification of paths to sustainable combinations of
growth and the output gap.
In the boom-bust
scenario, depicted in figure 1.D, above-trend output
growth during the expansion ultimately pushes output well
beyond potential for a persistent period. The resulting
overheating puts upward pressure on inflation. The
monetary policy response to reverse the inflation often
yields a decline in output, as depicted here, resulting in
a period of economic slack and a reversal of the rise in
inflation. This is the scenario from which we draw the
lesson that timely, typically preemptive, policy restraint
to avoid the excesses of a boom results in longer
expansions and avoids unnecessary fluctuations in both
output and inflation.
Where are We Relative
to Potential and Do We Need to Land?
To identify whether the initial conditions today
correspond to those in one of the panels of figure 1, we
have to assess where output is relative to its potential
and whether growth is above or below trend. This
assignment is more difficult than usual because structural
changes of uncertain dimension may have raised both the
level and the growth rate of potential output.
There is, for example, a
consensus that the NAIRU has declined since the early
1990s. That decline translates into an increase in the
level of potential output at any given time or a decline
in the output gap for a given level of output.
There is also a
consensus that the rate of growth of potential output is
higher today than during the twenty years preceding this
expansion. However, the degree to which these two
parameters have changed is not a settled issue. In
particular, some think that the rapid growth and low
unemployment rate of the past two years represent the
economy's new equilibrium (case 1.C), but others believe
that the economy has still been running ahead of potential
recently, despite structural changes. We should not be
surprised that a period of structural change would also be
one of heightened uncertainty about key parameters, such
as the NAIRU and trend growth.
Table
1 offers various estimates of the NAIRU and trend
growth, drawn from researchers, model-based forecasts,
assumptions incorporated in government budget projections,
and surveys of economic forecasters. These estimates
suggest that actual output is above potential (the
unemployment rate is below the NAIRU) and that actual
output growth has been above trend growth of potential.
Despite the
uncertainties, the consensus estimates of the NAIRU and
the growth of potential give us a hint about what type of
landing we should be aiming for and which of the scenarios
depicted in figure 1 best describe the economy's initial
conditions and prospects. The answer, it seems to me, is
that no scenario in figure 1 does justice to the complex
forces that have been in play during this expansion. I
believe that the prevailing macro configuration is best
described by some combination of figures 1.B, 1.C, or 1.D.
That is, even after we incorporate the estimated decline
in the NAIRU and the higher rate of growth of potential
(as reflected in figure 1.C), output is above potential
and output growth exceeds that of potential (as depicted
in figures 1.B and 1.D). If output were above potential,
we still would not know whether the outcome would be a
soft (1.B) or a hard (1.D) landing. To complete the
picture, we also have to rely on the temporary
disinflationary effects of favorable relative-price shocks
and the increase in the productivity trend that have
allowed the economy to operate, for a while, beyond
potential without suffering inflationary consequences.
Hard Landings
Associated with the Unwinding of Sector and Market
Imbalances
Much of the recent concern about the sustainability of
this expansion is, nevertheless, not related directly to
the balance between aggregate demand and aggregate supply.
Rather these concerns are related to perceived imbalances
in particular sectors or markets. Most notably, attention
has focused on equity prices, the personal saving rate,
the current account deficit, and debt burdens. The
unifying theme among this class of imbalances is that they
typically arise during an expansion, often as the result
of changing attitudes toward the perceived risk in the
economy or as a result of increased willingness to accept
risk. Many, though not all, of these imbalances are
financial in nature--for example, increases in leverage or
declines in liquidity and other margins of safety. These
developments typically play a role in supporting or
financing expansions. The resulting imbalances do not
typically induce a downturn by spontaneously reversing.
But they may act to magnify any downward forces that hit
the economy, increasing the depth and perhaps duration of
downturns. Hence, these factors play an important role in
both phases of the boom-bust scenario.
I associate many of the
second class of hard landing scenarios with the work of a
former colleague and friend, Hyman Minsky, who died in
1996. He emphasized the development of financial
vulnerabilities in expansions and their contribution to
serious recessions. In his view, serious recessions are
typically the result of a coincidence of adverse shocks on
an already vulnerable economy. Minsky emphasized the role
of vulnerabilities arising from financial imbalances,
including excessive debt burdens or increases in the price
of risky assets relative to safe assets.
Historical
Perspective on Market or Sector Imbalances
Figure
2 offers a historical perspective on equity prices,
the personal saving rate, the current account, and debt
burden. In each case, I identify a preferred measure of
each variable, scaling it relative to an appropriate
measure of output or income. I want to emphasize that we
cannot reach a judgment from these charts about whether
the perceived imbalance is real and serious, but we can at
least understand why concerns have been raised in each
case.
The chart for the stock
market, figure 2.A, shows the price-to-earnings ratio for
the S&P500 index, based on the trailing four-quarter
earnings. The current p/e ratio of about 32 compares with
an average of 16 since 1957 and a high before this
expansion of 22.3 in August 1987. The personal saving
rate, charted in figure 2.B, has declined in this episode
to a record low. The current account balance, pictured in
figure 2.C, is measured as the ratio to nominal gross
domestic product (GDP). This ratio has also declined to a
record low. In figure 2.D, I have charted the ratio of
debt service costs to disposable income for the household
sector, a preferred measure of the household debt burden.
It has been rising since the mid-1990s but remains below
the peak reached in the mid-1980s.
As I noted, none of
these diagrams definitively demonstrate that there is an
unsustainable imbalance. The point of the exercise is to
show why some have worried that there might be. It would
take a more detailed analysis than time permits to reach
an informed judgment about the risks in each case. And
when we were done with this more detailed analysis, we
could reasonably expect that we would still be left with
considerable uncertainty.
Common Sources of
Recent Developments
What I do want to focus on this afternoon are possible
common sources for the developments pictured in figure 2
and the relation of any imbalance between aggregate supply
and demand to those developments.
There are, I believe,
some common sources of the developments pictured in figure
2. First, these variables are all cyclically sensitive.
During expansions, equity prices tend to rise, although
they often decline before a downturn in the economy.
Discerning a consistent pattern for the saving rate during
an expansion from the chart is more difficult: Too many
other factors play a role. But regression analysis
indicates that the saving rate tends to move
countercyclically. The current account balance tends to
deteriorate if the expansion in the United States outpaces
that abroad, as has been the case in recent years. After
some point, the debt burden tends to increase sharply
during expansions, although it often turns before a
recession. But this cyclical expansion is not ordinary. It
is exceptional. The unemployment rate, for example, has
declined to a 30-year low. By some estimates, the output
gap is the widest since the early 1970s. The duration of
the expansion is about to set a record. It is therefore
not surprising that cyclically sensitive variables are
behaving exceptionally by historical standards.
Second, the composition
of output gains in this episode has also contributed to
the patterns in figure 2. Private domestic demand
typically is the driver of expansions, but its
contribution has been even greater than usual this time.
The direct contribution of federal government spending and
tax changes, reflected in the swing in the federal budget
from deficit to surplus, has been a net drag on growth.
The weakness of our trading partners and the crises among
emerging market economies contributed to the sharpness of
the decline in net exports. So the pace of domestic
private demand has been even stronger than the growth in
overall output. Private domestic spending has been driven,
in part, by the wealth effect arising from higher equity
prices, a situation that also helps to explain much of the
decline in the personal saving rate, and has been financed
by a higher household debt and by the tapping of foreign
saving.
Also the two types of
imbalances--an imbalance between aggregate demand and
aggregate supply and sector or market imbalances--could be
connected. Consider a situation in which growth is above
trend and output moves beyond capacity. If investors
misread these developments as sustainable and, therefore,
extrapolate the exceptional conditions, exceptional and
perhaps unsustainable movements in equity prices, the
saving rate, and debt burden might be encouraged.
Alternatively, a rise in equity prices that outstrips
fundamentals might contribute to a pace of private
domestic demand that ultimately takes output beyond
capacity; in this case, the market or sector imbalance
would be what contributed to the aggregate demand-supply
imbalance. It also seems quite possible, indeed likely,
that both these directions could operate simultaneously
and reinforce each other. Finally, market or sector
imbalances could possibly rise to worrisome proportions in
the absence of an imbalance between aggregate demand and
supply.
This analysis leaves us
with four possible combinations: (1) simultaneous
imbalances in both aggregate demand/supply and
market/sector variables; (2) simultaneous balance in each
class; (3) aggregate demand/supply imbalance accompanied
by balance in market/sector variables; and (4) aggregate
demand/supply balance accompanied by market/sector
imbalances. There are clearly a wide variety of opinions
about which of these combinations best describes the
current situation. Indeed, many observers, including
myself, are uncertain about which combination best fits
the current picture.
The problem in assessing
the risks associated with market/sector imbalances is not
only determining whether or not prevailing levels of these
variables constitute an imbalance in the first place but
also figuring out the circumstances and time frame over
which any true imbalance might be unwound. In addition,
the effects on the economy as a given imbalance is unwound
will depend importantly on interactions with other
imbalances and with events that trigger the unwinding of
the imbalance, as well as on the policy response. For
example, a stock market correction is typically triggered
by some adverse event so that the effect on the economy
will be the combined effects of the triggering event and
the stock market decline. A decline in the stock market
might also, for example, reduce confidence in the U.S.
economy and reduce the willingness of foreigners to
accumulate the increment in U.S. liabilities associated
with the current account deficit. And the net effect will
also depend on the policy response to the adverse effects
of the unwinding of any imbalances. As a result of these
considerations, simple multiplier exercises, such as the
effect on the economy of a given percentage decline in
equity prices, probably tell more about the econometric
model used than about prospects for the economy.
The Challenge for
Monetary Policy
The most important of the perceived imbalances I have
discussed today is, in my view, the possibility of an
overheated economy. In three of the four combinations of
aggregate demand/supply and market/sector imbalances, it
seems to me that the best approach would be to focus
directly on the aggregate demand/supply imbalance and
allow the indirect effects of such a policy to mitigate
any other imbalances. In addition, any other imbalances
are more likely to grow to worrisome proportions during an
unsustainable boom and are more likely to unwind in a
disruptive manner if confronted by rising inflation,
sharply higher interest rates in response to higher
inflation, and a subsequent recession. As a result, my
guess is that if we avoid the boom-bust scenario, we shall
have avoided the most serious of the other imbalances or
at least will be in a better position to absorb and
respond to the unwinding of other possible imbalances.
That leaves the
possibility that there might be cases when we face
market/sector imbalances in the absence of any aggregate
demand/supply imbalance. In such a case, the level and
growth of output are sustainable in the sense that they
are not putting pressure on inflation; but this aggregate
balance might be threatened subsequently by a spontaneous
unwinding of a market/sector imbalance. Alternatively, the
depth and duration of a downturn in response to some
future adverse shock might be aggravated by the unwinding
market/sector imbalances. What role can and should
monetary policy play in such a case? Policymakers will, I
expect, be reluctant to undermine macroeconomic
performance in the short run in an attempt to unwind a
perceived market/sector imbalance that might not be
serious or might unwind in a gradual and nondisruptive
fashion on its own. Furthermore, it is not obvious how to
unwind an excessive debt burden, to raise the personal
saving rate, or to narrow the current account deficit in a
sustainable way through monetary policy.
As a result, monetary
policy, in my view, needs to focus on achieving balance
between aggregate supply and aggregate demand. In pursuing
this course, monetary policy is confronted by two
competing challenges. The first is to allow the economy to
realize the benefits of any decline in the NAIRU and any
increase in trend growth. Supporting maximum sustainable
growth is very much the business of monetary policy. But
achieving maximum sustainable growth also is about
ensuring the sustainability of an expansion and hence
avoiding overheating. This is the second challenge today.
I view the efforts of the FOMC as precisely focused on
balancing these considerations.