My talk this afternoon focuses on model
building, forecasting, and policymaking and reflects a perspective shaped
both by my earlier experience and by my current responsibilities. Two
questions form the themes of my remarks: First, can the recent exceptional
performance of the U.S. economy be explained by traditional
macroeconometric models? Second, how should monetary policy respond to the
greater uncertainty both about forecasts and about the structural
relationships that have guided policy in the past?
As I wrestle with these questions, let
me also remind you that, as always, the views I express are my own. I am
not speaking on behalf of either the Board of Governors or the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Start with a Paradigm and End with a
Theory
Forecasting based on structural models,
my preferred approach, is not the only way to go. Diversity in our
profession, as in other professions, should be valued, not just tolerated.
Atheoretical statistical approaches, such as VARs, provide a cheap
alternative that, at least over short intervals, but not including the
current quarter, yield forecasts as accurate as those obtained from
significantly larger structural models. But let me offer some reasons why
I value the traditional model-based approach to forecasting and policy
analysis.
First, model-based forecasting begins
with a paradigm, a vision of how the economy works. I suppose the VAR
paradigm is that everything depends on everything else, though, in
practice, only a small number of variables can feasibly be included. But
clients and FOMC members want to know why, not just what. VARs can cheaply
tell us what. Model-based forecasts also provide a vision of why.
Second, and closely related, a
model-based forecast ends with a story. When I was in the private sector
and was asked what I did for a living I often responded that I was a
storyteller. My experience as a commercial forecaster taught me that
clients did not want to be buried in computer output. They demanded a
coherent story that tied the forecast together. A model-based forecast has
the ability to essentially explain itself.
Third, between the paradigm and the
story, macroeconometric models both rely on theory and reflect the
regularities found in the historical data. Models predict the impact of
new shocks through "tried and true" regularities.
Fourth, model-based forecasting allows a
forecaster to learn from past mistakes and indeed use past mistakes to
improve future forecasts. This is clearly one of the keys to good
forecasting. It is important to try to identify why you were wrong and to
establish what part or parts of the model were responsible for the
greatest errors. Responding to mistakes certainly can be aided by
statistical analysis, but there is often room for judgment--often
reflecting qualitative information that is difficult to incorporate into
the formal model.
Fifth, atheoretical statistical
approaches, as typically used, yield unconditional forecasts. Most
commercial and government forecasters very much want a conditional
forecast. Part of the explanation is the value of contingency analysis,
bracketing a baseline forecast with more optimistic and more pessimistic
forecasts and assessing the implications of major risks to the forecast.
Despite my appreciation of structural
models, I do not believe in mechanical model-based forecasting--estimating
the model and letting it make the forecast without intervention of the
forecaster. When Laurence H. Meyer & Associates won forecasting awards
and I was asked my formula for success, I reported my recipe: one part
science, one part judgment, and one part luck. The science was the model.
Art refers to the role of judgment. And luck--well, that speaks for
itself.
The Paradigm
Let me turn now to the paradigm. In
macroeconomics, I suppose, saying "the" paradigm seems wholly
out of place. So I mean the paradigm that is widely associated with
traditional macroeconometric models, though there are, of course, some
meaningful differences even within this class.
I view the traditional model paradigm as
an updated and eclectic version of the neoclassical synthesis. It is
defined by three key principles. First, the models are Keynesian in their
short-run properties. Specifically, they allow for sticky prices, and as a
result output is demand-determined in the short run. Second, the models
are classical in their long-run properties. Specifically output is
supply-determined in the long run, inflation is principally a monetary
phenomenon, real interest rates are determined by forces of productivity
and thrift, and nominal interest rates vary with inflation. Third, the
price-wage dynamics in the model, most often captured in the Phillips
curve, provide the equilibrating mechanism that guides the transition from
short run to long run. This sector essentially pins down just how sticky
prices are and how long it takes for price flexibility to push the economy
to a long-run equilibrium.
This paradigm is eclectic and inclusive.
It leaves room for the best of the macroeconomic insights of Keynes,
classical economists, supply siders, monetarists, and real-business-cycle
proponents. The neoclassical synthesis suggests separating the economy's
experience into short-run cycles and long-run growth. In early expressions
of this framework, the long-run or trend growth rate was generally viewed
as relatively stable, so that short-run movements in output could easily
be interpreted as movements in demand relative to long-run supply.
However, the experience of the 1990s, reinforcing the lessons of the
1970s, suggests that the earlier view of demand-induced variation around a
smooth long-term trend is overly simplistic.
As a result, today we better appreciate
the role of both short- and longer-run supply-side developments. In
addition, a narrow definition of supply shocks that covers only relative
price shocks--such as the oil price jumps in the 1970s--fails to do
justice to the range of supply-side developments that have so affected
output and inflation dynamics, particularly in the 1970s and 1990s. In
each episode, powerful supply-side shocks included significant changes in
our estimates of both the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment
(NAIRU) and the productivity trend. And we are not likely to be satisfied
again with a vision that begins from a presumed stable trend in output
growth.
Responding to Structural Change
That is a nice lead-in to the next
subject I want to introduce: the importance for both forecasters and
policymakers of responding to evidence of structural change. Part of the
explanation for the recent exceptional performance appears to be
structural changes that have enhanced the performance potential of the
economy. Specifically, there are signs of both a decline in the NAIRU and
an increase in trend growth. These changes suggest that the economy can
maintain stable inflation at a lower unemployment rate and, if not already
beyond the point of full employment, can grow faster without a threat of
overheating than had been the case for the previous two decades or more.
The potential for structural change is a
difficult problem for macroeconometric models, built on a base of a
relatively long time series and therefore giving relatively little weight
to the most recent observations in parameter estimation. Two errors can be
made with respect to structural change. First, the model builder could
fail to account in a timely way for actual structural change and therefore
make poor forecasts. Second, the forecaster could quickly translate errors
in the model into structural change when in fact no such change has
occurred. The latter adjustment might nevertheless mop up the errors for a
few quarters but would ultimately undermine the accuracy of forecasts
going forward.
But just how sure do we need to be
before we integrate into our forecasts and into our policymaking new
estimates of key parameters? We are taught classical econometric
techniques for testing for structural change, and these set a high hurdle
for recognizing structural breaks. But does it make sense for a forecaster
or a policymaker to insist on having a 90 percent to 95 percent degree of
confidence that a structural change has occurred before he or she reflects
such a change in a forecast or policy decision? In testing for structural
change, we also tend to emphasize regime changes where parameters change
from one stable value to another. This seems particularly restrictive for
some parameters--specifically the NAIRU and trend growth--that can be and
should be expected to evolve over time.
At the Fed, reflecting no doubt the
demands of having to make policy in a world of incomplete information and
the continuing questions about the estimates of the NAIRU and trend
productivity, the staff has been continuously updating its estimates of
both parameters. These revised estimates have been instrumental in
conditioning the staff forecasts of both inflation and real economic
activity and have clearly played an important role in the policy
deliberations and actions.
One technique that increasingly has been
applied--inside and outside the Fed--is time-varying parameter estimation.
Instead of beginning with a prior of a constant coefficient over a long
period, the point of departure is the presumption that parameters change
over time. The technique views errors from a particular equation as
embodying both random noise and indications of structural change. It then
allows for a continuous updating of key parameters to capture the evolving
change in structure. I find this approach especially appealing for the
estimation of parameters such as the NAIRU and trend growth. In both
cases, there are grounds for expecting the parameter to evolve over time,
but limited ability to model the sources of this evolution. We therefore
try to extract the parameter from estimation of some structural equation,
such as a Phillips curve in the case of the NAIRU or an equation for the
demand for labor in the case of productivity. In doing so, it is
constructive to use an estimation technique flexible enough to admit the
possibility of gradual change in these parameters.
New Parameters or a "New
Economy"?
A particularly important issue today is
whether the evidence of structural change points to a change in
paradigm--to a so-called new economy--or whether it can be adequately
expressed as a change in the parameters within the traditional paradigm.
This distinction goes to the very heart of the issue facing forecasters
and policymakers today.
I appreciate that the traditional
paradigm provides less direction in forecasting and policy analysis when
it admits time-varying parameters for the NAIRU and trend productivity
growth. But if the data suggest evolution in these parameters over time,
both forecasters and policymakers have to be alert to the importance of
continually updating their estimates of these parameters and do the best
they can within this more challenging environment. It is true, however,
that the optimal strategy for monetary policy might be affected by the
higher degree of uncertainty surrounding key parameters in the model. I
will return to this theme later.
But, from a modeling or even analytical
perspective, what framework is offered to replace the traditional
paradigm? I am not a proponent of the new economy school. I admit that I
do not fully understand what new paradigm is being offered as the heir
apparent to the old paradigm. In the extreme, it appears to hold that
there are no limits--no level of capacity that, if exceeded, induces
higher inflation and no trend rate of growth that, if consistently
exceeded, implies an increase in production relative to capacity leading,
over time, to excess demand and higher inflation. I have to admit the
absence of such limits makes absolutely no sense to me.
At any rate, I still believe that the
traditional neoclassical synthesis is the best and most resilient
framework for understanding macroeconomic developments. So my approach is
to stick with the paradigm and to change the parameters. Many who are
viewed as new economy proponents can perhaps be understood, within this
paradigm, as believing in one or more of the following: the NAIRU is lower
than the 5 percent to 5 � percent estimate that I now use, trend
productivity growth is higher than the 2 � percent rate I now feel
comfortable with, and productivity growth is still rising. In addition,
new economy proponents may be interpreted as favoring a policy that probes
for the limits of how low the NAIRU and how high trend growth might be. In
light of uncertainties about these parameters, this policy would encourage
a less pre-emptive and more reactive approach to the threat of higher
inflation. But if we are all operating within a well-defined paradigm, we
can more effectively marshal the evidence from the data to support our
individual judgments.
Implications of the Paradigm for
Inflation and Growth
Today, the challenge of explaining
recent economic performance leads me to focus my attention on the
implications of the paradigm sketched above for economic growth and
inflation.
The growth framework embodied in this
paradigm is generally the neoclassical growth model in which long-run
growth is tied down by exogenous trends in population and multi-factor
productivity. Capital deepening--that is, increases in capital relative to
labor--can also have an influence on the growth of labor productivity.
A change in the trend rate of growth, in
this framework, would therefore reflect some combination of exogenous
changes in population, multi-factor productivity trends, and endogenous
capital deepening. In the current episode, the increase in the estimate of
trend labor productivity from the 1.1 percent rate widely assumed coming
into this expansion to what I expect has become the consensus estimate of
2 � percent today has three components.
First, methodological
changes--specifically revisions to measures of the price level and the
recent accounting change to include software as a capital
expenditure--have raised the measured trend rate of increase in labor
productivity over a longer period. Together these revisions in methodology
have contributed about 0.4 percentage point to the increase in the trend
growth rate relative to the earlier 1.1 percent estimate.
The second component is capital
deepening, reflecting the high rate of net investment in this expansion
and the resulting increase in the ratio of capital services to labor. The
third component is a possible increase in the trend rate of growth in
multi-factor productivity.
Having asserted the primacy of monetary
forces in determining inflation in the long run, some may wonder at my
well-known commitment to the Phillips curve. You shouldn't! The Phillips
curve, as I hope is well known, does not pin down the long-run inflation
rate. In the vertical long-run Phillips curve specification, at least, any
stable inflation rate is compatible with equilibrium in the labor and
product markets. Instead, the Phillips curve specifies short-run inflation
dynamics--how and why inflation moves from one path to another--and
highlights the critical role of excess demand as a proximate source of
rising inflation.
We learned in the 1970s that excess
demand is not always the driving force behind movements in inflation.
Sometimes excess demand dominates near-term movements in inflation, and
sometimes supply shocks overwhelm the effects of overall supply/demand
balance in the labor and product markets. As a result, the paradigm now
always incorporates supply shocks as a second proximate source of changes
in inflation.
I find it useful to distinguish two
types of supply shocks: first, relative price shocks, such as increases in
the price of oil or food, unrelated to the balance between supply and
demand in the overall economy; and second, the effect of an unexpected
increase in the productivity trend. We are more used to incorporating the
former than the latter, but recent experience has, I believe, been a
mixture of both.
Modeling the Effect of a Productivity
Shock
One of the most fascinating and complex
shocks to evaluate is a shift in the underlying productivity trend. It is
difficult to determine when such a shift takes place, both because
productivity has such a powerful cyclical component and because
productivity has a fairly large noise component. In addition, when a shift
does take place, sometimes its force diminishes over time. In other cases,
we have very little basis for predicting its sustainability. Another
complication is that some adjustments to the productivity trend reflect
methodological changes--for example, improvements in the estimates of
price indexes. These affect the estimate of productivity over a long
period but do not translate into an acceleration in productivity growth in
the current episode. Finally, there are a wide variety of repercussions
from an increase in the productivity trend.
Higher trend productivity, of course,
means a higher average growth rate for real GDP. But it has profound
effects on demand as well as supply. This is certainly one of the most
important lessons of the current episode. A first inclination might be to
assume that higher trend productivity translates into a more rapid advance
in supply relative to demand, tilting the balance between supply and
demand in the economy. In fact, a higher productivity trend also appears
to produce perhaps as powerful a stimulus to demand.
Several channels are at work here.
First, the technological shock that underpins higher productivity
typically carries with it enhanced profit opportunities, spurring
investment. Second, the same profit opportunities and associated optimism
can be expected to drive equity prices higher, both reducing the financing
cost of new investment and spurring consumer spending via the wealth
effect. Third, expectations of higher permanent income may contribute to
higher consumer spending. On balance, in the short run, demand may
increase as much as supply, or even more so. The point is that we cannot
assume the higher trend productivity eliminates concern about overheating.
Nevertheless, even if higher
productivity has an equal impact on demand as on supply, it will still
tend to damp inflationary pressures in the short run. This is again one of
the most powerful lessons of the current episode. Let me explain in some
detail how an unexpected increase in productivity growth operates as a
temporary favorable supply shock in the traditional paradigm. I begin from
a wage-price specification of the Phillips curve--that is, from an
equation that explains the rate of growth of nominal compensation in terms
of inflation and the gap between the unemployment rate and the NAIRU. Such
a specification also should include trend growth in labor productivity as
an explanatory variable. Such a specification is necessary to ensure that,
in the long run, when unemployment on average equals the NAIRU, nominal
compensation increases at a rate equal to the sum of inflation and the
trend rate of increase in labor productivity.
An increase in the productivity growth
trend will have a temporary disinflationary effect if the specification of
the wage-price sector incorporates an asymmetric response of wages and
prices to the change in the productivity growth trend. Specifically,
nominal compensation is assumed to respond more slowly than prices to a
change in the trend rate of labor productivity. Of course, both wages and
prices respond with a lag to an increase in the productivity trend because
it takes time to sort out whether higher productivity is cyclical, just
normal quarterly variability or a shift in the underlying trend. But the
more sluggish adjustment of nominal wages relative to prices reflects
longer nominal contracts for wages than prices; possible information
asymmetries (faster learning about the change in trend by businesses than
by workers); and perhaps the role of slowly changing wage norms governing
wage bargaining.
As a result, there is initially almost
no effect on nominal compensation from a change in the trend rate of
productivity growth. With nearly unchanged compensation and higher
productivity, firms find their costs lower and their profits higher than
expected. Competition then results in price declines, eroding the profits
and resulting in lower inflation than would otherwise have occurred. The
lower inflation in turn moderates nominal compensation gains; that is, the
same real increases now require smaller nominal gains. The result is a
virtuous cycle of lower inflation, lower nominal compensation, and lower
inflation.
However, productivity shocks--like
relative price supply shocks--result only in temporary departures of
inflation from the underlying rate justified by longer-run influences such
as money growth and shorter-run cyclical influences such as utilization
rates. Once the influence of productivity growth in the wage change
equation converges to its effect in the price equation, the asymmetry that
drives the disinflationary effect of an unexpected increase in the
productivity trend dissipates, assuming that productivity growth
stabilizes.
Evolution of the Traditional Model
I now want to discuss four developments
of special importance in the evolution of macroeconometric model building,
building on the models in place by the late 1960s: the modeling of
inflation dynamics, the incorporation of international linkages, the role
of policy reaction functions, and the modeling of expectations.
The underlying core of the life-cycle
model of consumption, neoclassical models of investment and labor demand,
and inventory-theoretic money demand remain intact. The most important
change was the transition from a Phillips curve that allowed a long-run
trade-off between inflation and unemployment to the vertical, natural-rate
specification. This was well entrenched by the mid-1970s and was
accompanied by a more consistent treatment of inflation in the models,
including more careful differentiation of nominal and real interest rates.
In addition, by the mid 1970s the models moved to explicitly incorporate
supply shocks, at least the relative-price type of shocks.
The second development of special
importance is the change in the international sector owing to the
increased openness of the U.S. economy as well as the effect of the change
in the exchange rate regime. Today, imports are a more important part of
the short-run dynamics of the model, including a significant role as a
stabilizer of shocks to domestic demand. But this openness also has
subjected the U.S. economy to shocks from abroad and forced forecasters to
pay increasing attention to international linkages and incorporate more
details about them. The recent episode of troubles among Asian emerging
economies was outside the boundaries of coverage in some models, and
adjustment factoring of import and export equations was required to
compensate. The experience suggests the importance of sufficiently broad
measures of foreign economic activity and exchange rates in models,
increasing the span of the world that forecasters have to consider in
their forecasts for the United States.
The shift to a flexible exchange rate
regime and the increased mobility of capital also has sharpened the
responsiveness of real exchange rates to real interest rate differentials
across countries. Combined with the increased importance of imports and
exports, the heightened responsiveness of real exchange rates has
increased the importance of the exchange rate channel in the transmission
of monetary policy. In the Board staff's model, that channel now accounts
for about a third of the responsiveness of aggregate demand to changes in
interest rates over a one- to three-year period. Nevertheless, the overall
interest sensitivity of aggregate demand appears to be nearly unchanged,
at least until the last couple of years, because the increased role of
exchange rates has been offset largely by the decreased interest
sensitivity of housing due to the elimination of Regulation Q and
innovations in financing home purchases. In the past few years, however,
the sensitivity of the economy to interest rates may have increased as a
result of a more powerful interest-induced wealth effect. This development
reflects the increase in the wealth-income ratio produced by the
extraordinary rise in equity prices over the last several years.
Finally, international developments
clearly are helping to restrain U.S. inflation. No doubt the appreciation
of the dollar from the spring of 1995 through mid-1998 has played a
powerful role. So has the lack of conformity in the business cycles in
Europe and Japan relative to the United States, an especially important
factor because increased trade flows make capacity more of a global
concept in some industries. I expect that our inflation performance would
have been less exceptional if the cycles in Europe and Japan had precisely
matched our own and if the dollar had remained stable over the past three
years.
A third evolution in structural models
is the use of reaction functions to characterize monetary policy. At
Laurence H. Meyer & Associates, we offered our clients a choice of
monetary policy regime. They could treat a short-term interest rate, a
measure of the money supply, or nonborrowed reserves as an exogenous
variable (determined by discretionary policy) or switch on a policy
reaction function (explicitly treating monetary policy actions as
endogenous responses to economic developments). All the options have their
uses, but in a period when there is serious doubt about the stability of
money demand, policy reaction functions provide an alternative approach to
anchoring the determination of short-term interest rates.
Ironically, policy reaction functions
appear to be used more in models at the Federal Reserve, where monetary
policy is made, than in the private sector, where monetary policy must be
forecast. Many forecasters prefer to rely on their interpretation of what
various FOMC members say, or what one especially significant member of the
FOMC says or does not say (and I am definitely not talking about myself),
in setting the funds rate in the initial quarter. But after the first
quarter or two, a policy reaction function provides a systematic way to
relate monetary policy to the evolution of the forecast. A policy rule is
also consistent with my answer when someone asks me, usually in jest, how
the federal funds rate will change over the next several meetings. They
are initially surprised that I would even answer such a question. But I do
answer, and honestly. The answer is: It depends. Specifically, it depends
on how utilization rates, growth, and inflation change over time and, at
times, on changes in the forecast of these variables going forward.
The last major change in modeling is the
ongoing attempt to better incorporate the role of expectations and to more
richly model the formation of expectations. Most traditional macro models
continue to model expectations though distributed lags, an approach that
captures in a rough way both adjustment costs and expectations formation.
A backward-looking adaptive expectation framework remains the conventional
practice, at least in large-scale commercial macro-econometric models.
This is an area in which the recently introduced FRB-US model, the
successor to the MPS model at the Board, has made significant innovations.
The thrust of the new work is to
separate macro-dynamics into adjustment-cost and expectation-formation
components, with adjustment costs imposing a degree of inertia and
expectations introducing a forward-looking element into the dynamics. The
net result is a structure that integrates rational expectations into a
sticky-price model.
The model retains the neoclassical
synthesis of the MPS model--short-run output dynamics based on sticky
prices and long-run classical properties associated with price
flexibility--and therefore produces multiplier results, in both the short
and longer runs, that are very similar to those produced by the MPS model.
The result is that the model produces, for the most part, what may be the
better of two worlds--a modern form and traditional results. But the
better-articulated role of expectations in the new model also allows a
richer analysis of the response to those policy actions which might have
immediate effects on expectations of key variables such as inflation and
interest rates.
Can the Traditional Paradigm Explain
Recent Experience?
When I talk about the challenge for
monetary policy in the current environment, I often see a look of surprise
on the faces in the audience. What challenge? The economy is performing
exceptionally. The only challenge, I am often told, is to not screw it up.
But to meet this daunting challenge we must confront two others: The first
is to understand the source of the exceptional performance. The second is
to position monetary policy in light of the answer to the first challenge.
From the perspective of the traditional
models, the current expansion carries two surprises: the strength of
domestic demand, explainable in part by the unexpectedly sharp increase in
equity prices, and even more impressive, the decline in inflation (this
year confined to core measures) despite steadily rising labor utilization
rates, to a level well below virtually anyone's estimate of the NAIRU.
Many, though perhaps not all, the
explanations for this exceptional performance fit well enough within the
framework of traditional models through some combination of normal model
error, exogenous shocks, and changes in parameters, the latter reflecting
structural changes in the economy.
A significant part of the surprise in
domestic demand reflects the unexpectedly sharp run-up in equity prices.
The stock market boom has significantly lowered the private saving rate
and boosted consumer spending, contributed to the buoyancy of the housing
market, and encouraged a more robust pace of business fixed investment by
reducing the real cost of capital.
Virtually all traditional models, I
expect, have underpredicted the dramatic rise in stock prices.
Interestingly, the revisions to estimated trend productivity growth
(implying a higher sustainable rate of increase in earnings) have greatly
reduced the over-valuation implicit in such models, at least through 1998.
Still, here again we face the task of interpreting large and persistent
errors in a structural equation. Does this pattern of errors suggest a
persistent over-valuation in equity prices or is it an indication of a
structural break? Specifically, are there grounds for believing that there
has been a significant decline in the equity premium, justifying a higher
equilibrium price-earnings ratio? Whether the higher equity prices are
being driven by structural change (and therefore might be sustainable) or
are driven by forces more subject to reversal, they may have a similar
effect on aggregate demand and encourage a similar response by monetary
policy. That is the point I want to emphasize. I will not (not only
because I cannot) resolve the question of whether or not higher equity
prices are fully justified by fundamentals.
I have offered two stories to explain
the economy's recent exceptional performance--specifically, the
combination of robust growth and rising utilization rates and stable to
declining inflation. The first I have called "temporary bliss."
This story focuses on a coincidence of reinforcing relative price shocks
that have restrained inflation and allowed the economy to move beyond
sustainable limits for a while without inflationary consequences. The
decline in energy prices over 1997 and 1998, the appreciation of the
dollar from the spring of 1995 through mid-1998, and the sharp slowing in
cost increases for health insurance are the major players in this story. I
have called the second story "permanent bliss." It focuses on
structural changes--specifically the decline in the NAIRU and the increase
in trend productivity growth--that have enhanced the performance of the
economy.
When I first offered these explanations,
I noted that neither one alone appeared to do justice to recent experience
but that the weights attached to each were still important in designing
the appropriate monetary policy response. I will return to this theme
below.
Since I first offered these alternative
stories, it has become clearer to me that the increase in trend
productivity growth has been the star of this episode. It also has become
clearer to me that an unexpected improvement in the productivity trend is
a development that fits into both the temporary- and permanent-bliss
stories. If it persists, the higher trend productivity will have a
profound effect on rising living standards. But a critical question--both
for the forecast and for monetary policy--is what are the consequences of
a permanent increase in productivity for inflation.
Here I draw upon the model of inflation
dynamics presented earlier. First, trend productivity has nothing to do
with the rate of inflation in the long run. Inflation is a monetary
phenomenon and will be pinned down--for better or worse--by the decisions
made about monetary policy. Second, an unexpected increase in the
productivity trend is, as I emphasized earlier, a very powerful favorable
supply shock. The result is a significant and, though temporary, somewhat
persistent disinflationary force on the economy. I don't see how we could
possibly explain the recent episode without starting from this
proposition. And as I noted earlier, this perspective is perfectly
consistent with a carefully specified but traditional macro model--new
parameters in the old paradigm.
But the key message is that old rules
still apply to the new limits. Overheating still eventually results if the
growth of demand exceeds the growth of supply for long enough, driving the
unemployment rate below the NAIRU. Excess demand in labor markets still
ultimately puts upward pressure on nominal compensation.
So where are we in this process? That
depends on whether the updrift in trend productivity growth is ongoing or
over. That is, to some degree, unknowable today, although we have some
tangible evidence about future productivity (via capital deepening) from
the current pace of net investment and the forecast for investment going
forward. And it also depends on how low the NAIRU is today and whether it
is still changing. But it is quite clear that the other source of supply
shocks--the relative price shocks--have all dissipated or reversed,
raising the risk of higher inflation going forward. In addition, it would
take a rather large additional increment to productivity growth to prevent
the diminishing effect from this source from causing some uptick in
inflation.
Implications for Monetary Policy
So what does all this imply for the
conduct of monetary policy? First, policymakers have to sort out the
degree to which the story is temporary bliss versus permanent bliss. The
answer has a critical bearing on the nature of the challenge facing
monetary policy. Second, policymakers have to adjust their strategy to
take into account the greater uncertainty about key parameters and the
greater difficulty in forecasting in this environment.
If the favorable inflation outcome of
recent years results importantly from the temporary-bliss story, favorable
supply shocks have allowed the economy to move beyond the point of
sustainable capacity for a while without inflationary consequences. If
this is correct, as the favorable supply shocks dissipate or reverse, it
will not be possible to remain at prevailing utilization rates without
inflationary consequences. Two choices will ultimately present themselves
under this scenario. Either the economy will move to a path of higher
inflation or policy will encourage a transition to a more
sustainable--though less exceptional--state before the upturn in inflation
takes hold or at least before it yields a significant rise in the
inflation rate.
If the permanent-bliss story is the
greater reason for the favorable inflation outcome, then the role of
monetary policy is dramatically different. In this case, policy should
accommodate the new, enhanced performance characteristics of the economy
and not constrain it on the basis of out-dated measures of capacity and
speed limits. We can perhaps best interpret the new-economy argument as an
acceptance of the permanent-bliss interpretation of recent experience and,
as a result, offering more support than the temporary-bliss argument
offers for an accommodating monetary policy. However, even here, monetary
policy would have to be alert both to the effect of a higher productivity
trend on demand as well as supply and to the implication of the model that
an increase in trend productivity raises the economy's real equilibrium
interest rate. Therefore, even under the permanent-bliss story,
policymakers have to be alert in the short run to the possibility of
overheating and, at over a longer run, to aligning the real federal funds
rate with its higher equilibrium value.
It seems inescapable that this episode
has been characterized by both a variety of shocks and by important
changes in key parameters. As a result, there is an unusual degree of
uncertainty about the structure of the economy and the forecast going
forward. Every year, for example, we forecast slowing growth and rising
inflation. Then we spend the coming year trying to explain why we have
achieved faster-than-expected growth and lower-than-expected inflation.
The cumulative effect of this exercise is that it seems less attractive to
base current policy on forecasts. The implication is that policy
inevitably becomes more reactive as it becomes less pre-emptive.
Some very interesting work at the Board
has focused on the implications of uncertainty about the measurement of
the output gap (the gap between actual and potential output). This
uncertainty is, to an important degree, the result of the uncertainty
about the estimate of the NAIRU, given that the NAIRU is critical in
pinning down the level of potential output. But uncertainty about the rate
of growth in potential output also has been an important factor in the
mismeasurement of the output gap. Historically, estimates of the NAIRU,
the output gap, and trend growth have been revised substantially over
time, implying that policymakers often have made decisions based on an
assessment of the output gap that later was judged to be seriously
incorrect. How should policymakers respond to this problem?
First, we should recognize, as I have
emphasized earlier, that the NAIRU and trend growth can change, and have
changed, over time, and we should be sensitive to the importance of
updating our estimates of these parameters in response to incoming data on
inflation, unemployment, and other variables. As I noted earlier, this is
very much what we have been doing at the Fed. Second, to the extent that a
greater uncertainty remains about the measurement of the output gap, it
may be prudent to attenuate the aggressiveness with which real interest
rates are adjusted in response to movements in the output gap. That does
not mean that movements in the output gap should be ignored. In addition,
such an attenuated response, in my view, makes sense only in a region
around your best estimate of potential output (or the NAIRU). Once the
unemployment rate falls far enough below your best estimate of the NAIRU,
for example, it would be prudent to return to a more normal responsiveness
of interest rates to further declines in the unemployment rate. In my
judgment, we are already in a range in which such a normal response to
further declines in the unemployment rate is warranted.
Given the initial conditions of robust
growth and high utilization rates, at least with respect to the labor
market, and given the clear evidence that the previously favorable price
shocks are dissipating or reversing, we cannot, in my view, afford to
withdraw entirely from a forward-looking policy that is built on our best
estimates of the structure of the economy and inflation dynamics. While
one could interpret recent policy tightenings as a reversal of earlier
easings, the fact is that any policy action has to be justified on the
basis of how it contributes going forward to achieving the broad macro
objectives assigned to monetary policy. Therefore, for my part, I view the
last policy action as an example of still pre-emptive monetary policy,
designed to mitigate the risk of higher inflation going forward,
especially in light of the threat that robust growth would push already
high utilization rates even higher.
I continue to believe that the
fundamental challenge for monetary policy is to facilitate a transition
from the current exceptional but unsustainable state to a more
sustainable, though still excellent, state. The transition might well
occur while we remain spectators of an economy that slows spontaneously
and as a result of recent policy actions. Or it could involve our more
active participation. It depends!